giovedì 4 marzo 2010

A Visual History of the Federal Reserve System

A Visual History of the Federal Reserve System
1914 - 2009
Free Digital Edition

This is a free digital edition of a chart created by John Paul Koning. It has been designed to be appreciated on paper as a 24x36 inch display. If you enjoy this chart please consider buying the paper version at www.financialgraphart.com. Buyers of the chart will recieve a bonus chart “reimagining” the history of the Fed’s balance sheet. Alternatively, if you have found this chart useful but don’t want to buy a paper edition, consider donating to me at http://www.financialgraphart.com/donate. It took me many months to compile the data and design it, any support would be much appreciated. For collectors, a limited 10 chart edition signed and numbered by the designer is available at
http://www.financialgraphart.com/collector.
John Paul Koning, 2009


FOR BETTER OR FOR WORSE, the Federal Reserve has been governing the monetary system of the United States since 1914. This chart maps the rise of the Fed from its origins as a relatively minor institution, often controlled by Presidents and the United States Department of the Treasury, into an independent and powerful body that rivals the Presidency in terms of prominence. Multiple data series including the Fed’s balance sheet, interest rates and spreads, reserve requirements, chairmen, inflation, recessions, and more help chronicle this rise. While this chart can only tell part of the complex story of the Fed, we trust it will be a valuable reference tool to anyone curious about the evolution of this very influential yet controversial institution.

1914-1936

IN ITS FIRST TWO YEARS, the Fed was a passive institution. It set its lending rate above the market rate, making it unprofitable for banks to turn to it for loans. As a result, discounts were negligible. This changed in 1917 with the entrance of the US into World War I. The Fed, nowadays largely independent from other branches of the government, was then controlled by the Treasury Secretary. To help pay for looming war bills, the Fed was converted into a war-finance body.
Amendments to the Federal Reserve Act paved the way. The original Federal Reserve Act emphasized that discounts were be made on “real bills” principles; only short term bills based on commercial transactions would be eligible for Fed loans. In 1916, authorities began to break with this principle when the Fed was given permission to lend to banks on the security of government debt. In 1917, these “Section 13.8” advances were made “eligible” as collateral for notes.
The 1917 amendments also reduced the backing requirement for Federal Reserve notes. Prior to 1917, all notes had to be double-backed by 100% real bills, and 40% gold. After 1917, notes need only be backed by 60% bills and 40% gold. At the same time, reserve requirements were lowered by Congress from 18% to 13%, and a preferential lending rate introduced on all 13.8 advances secured by government Liberty Bonds. The effect of all these changes was to dramatically increase the Fed’s ability to issue notes. The private sector bought large quantities of government war bonds, then used these bonds as security to get Fed 13.8 advances at below-market rates. In effect, they profited every time they transacted with the Fed. As a result of the Fed’s subsidization of government bond purchases, the dollar’s purchasing power plummeted. Friedman & Schwartz estimate that 5% of the government’s war expenses were paid for by the Fed’s “inflation tax”.
The events after the 1929 stock market crash brought many changes to the Fed’s balance sheet and operating procedures.
The Emergency Construction, Emergency Banking, and Industrial Advances Acts granted the Fed power to extend loans to non-member individuals, partnerships, and corporations under certain conditions by adding sections 13.3, 13.13, and 12b to the Federal Reserve Act. The First Glass-Steagall Act brought in even larger modifications, firstly by allowing the Fed to make advances on “any satisfactory collateral” to member banks through Section 10b advances, and secondly by allowing government securities purchased in the open market to stand as sufficient backing for Federal Reserve notes. The latter freed the Fed to monetize government debt via open market operations and not just discounts. Government debt on the Fed’s balance sheet would grow inexorably from then on, further moving the Fed away from its “real bills” origins. Also significant were legislative changes that began to de-link the dollar from the gold standard. In 1933, private holdings of gold were criminalized. Gold was brought to the Federal Reserve for notes, and on January 30, 1934 this gold was transferred to the US Treasury in return for certificates. The next day the dollar was devalued from $20.67/oz to $35/oz. The capital gain, therefore, was credited to the Treasury, not the Fed. The $2.3 billion rise in Treasury cash, a liability of the Fed, became the war-chest of the Treasury and its new Exchange Stabilization Fund, which would dominate monetary policy to 1951, rendering the Fed a passive partner.

1936-1968

MUCH LIKE WWI, the Fed was harnessed to finance the Second World War. Reserve requirements were reduced to allow member banks to expand lending for the war effort, and a preferential discount rate of 0.5% was set for loans collateralized by government debt. Unlike WWI, the latter was hardly used. Far more attractive to member banks were the open market buying rates set by the Fed. By offering to buy all government t-bills at 0.35% and long term bonds at 2.5%, the Fed ensured that government debt prices would never fall. This price-fixing scheme allowed the government to issue huge amounts of Victory Loans to finance the war, and guaranteed the capital safety of the private sector’s investment.
The result was one of the fastest increases in the government bond portion of the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet to date. At the same time, inflation jumped to its highest level since the early 20s. War-time wage and price controls succeeded in reducing overt inflation, but the effects manifested themselves as shortages and reductions in quality. The removal of price controls in 1946 resulted in a large spike in inflation rates. After the war’s end, Fed officials increasingly agitated for more independence from the Treasury in setting monetary policy.
With the onset of the Korean War, it pressed for an end to the WWII-era 2.5% rate peg, which the Treasury expected it to maintain to help finance the newest war effort. The conflict between the two bodies culminated in the 1951 Accord, in which the Fed finally earned its independence and the 2.5% ceiling was discontinued. The Korean War would not be financed by the Fed.
In 1959, the Fed agreed to one of the only reductions in its power to date. Section 13b of the Federal Reserve Act, passed in 1934 to allow the Fed to lend directly to businesses for working capital purposes, was removed.
The dollar’s link to gold was an important issue after WWII. The war-time accumulation of government bonds on its balance sheet threatened the 40% gold backing requirement for Federal Reserve notes and deposits. Rather than sell government bonds to regain the 40% level, the requirement was legally reduced to 25% for notes and deposits in 1945.
The post-war Bretton Woods agreement stipulated that the world’s currencies would be fixed to the dollar, and the dollar would be fixed and convertible at $35/oz. Large US foreign expenditures led to an accumulation of dollars overseas, and beginning in 1958 these were returned to the US at ever increasing amounts for gold. Attempts to stem the gold outflow, including the formation of the London Gold Pool and the Interest Equalization Tax, failed. In 1965 the Fed, lacking gold, further reduced gold backing for Fed deposits from 25% to 0%. Bretton Woods was collapsing.

1968-1999

IN EARLY 1968, private sector purchases of gold in London exploded. The London Gold Pool, formed by the Fed and a number of European central banks to cap the London price at $35, was unable to suppress the buying. The pool was disbanded in early 1968 and the market price leaped above $40, the result being two prices for the dollar; the official one at $35, and a significantly higher market price.
The Fed simultaneously reduced the 25% gold backing requirement to 0% as outflows of gold threatened to bring holdings below their legal limit. The dollar remained convertible into gold though, and central banks continued to bring their dollars to New York to claim the metal.Vietnam War expenses and setbacks further undermined confidence in the dollar, and in 1971 Nixon decided to solve the outflow problem by simply removing the dollar’s convertibility. With one pillar of Bretton Wood’s undermined – convertibility to gold – only one remained; fixed exchange rates to the dollar. The Smithsonian Agreement tried but failed to fix rates, and in 1973 all currencies were all allowed to float. Bretton Woods was dead. Gold would cease to be an important asset on the Fed’s balance sheet, replaced by government debt.
On the domestic front, the Fed’s discount window was increasingly utilized to support insolvent institutions, breaking with prior central banking tradition of lending to illiquid but solvent banks only. Attempts failed to recruit the Fed to help bailout Penn Central, but in 1974 the discount window was crucial in supporting Franklin National, a failing bank. Continental Illinois, crippled by the collapse of Penn Square two years before, was kept on life support by the Fed in 1984, and most of the large Texas banks found support from the Fed when they failed in 1988. All these actions gave the impression that the Fed had adopted a policy of “too big to fail”, in which large and politically connected institutions received favourable treatment from the Fed when they went bust, but smaller banks didn’t.
Several major changes to the Federal Reserve Act modified the Fed’s mandate. A 1977 amendment added section 2A to the Act, stipulating for the first time the Fed’s dual role of promoting stable prices and maximum employment. The Monetary Control Act of 1980 allowed foreign government debt to serve as collateral for reserve notes, removed the penalty on 10b advances, and expanded the discount window to allow non-member banks to access it. Finally, a small change in 1991 to Section 13.3 - a dormant 1930s era power that allowed the Fed to lend to individuals, corporations, and businesses on limited collateral in emergencies – allowed for an almost unlimited range of collateral to be accepted by the Fed. This small but vital change would serve as the legal foundation for the Fed’s massive extension of loans during the 2007-09 credit crisis.

1999-2009

MUCH OF THIS ERA’S HISTORY remains to be written, but it includes the largest expansion in the Fed’s balance sheet to date, dwarfing the WWI growth of discounts, the 1934 gold revaluation, and the WWII expansion. The expansion’s effect on employment, GDP, credit, and confidence in the dollar continue to play out.
Several changes to the Federal Reserve Act are notable. In 1999, prior to the year 2000 date change, Section 10a and 10b advances were made eligible to serve as collateral for Federal Reserve notes, increasing the Fed’s ability to issue notes should the new century start in crisis. This was superseded in 2003 when any asset held by the Fed was made eligible as collateral for notes, removing from the Act the last vestiges of the “real bills” doctrine which originally limited eligibility to short term commercial bills. Finally, the Fed was given a new monetary tool in 2008 when it was authorized to pay interest on reserves for the first time.
The cumulative changes to the Federal Reserve Act have given the Fed the ability to act in ways it never would have been capable of in times past. When solvent banks’ demand for liquidity exploded, it was able to create facilities like TAF to meet this demand. But loans to Maiden Lane I-III, authorized under Section 13.3, have supported the questionable assets of insolvent non-banks Bear Stearns and American International Group. Section 13.3 is also the legal basis for loans made by a myriad of facilities, including the CPFF, AMLF, PDCF, and TALF (see notes in legend for definitions). At the same time, Fed purchases of government debt have fallen. Not since the early 1920s has the Fed held such a large proportion of private sector debt on its balance sheet.
On the liabilities side of the balance sheet, the low level of reserves encouraged by the 1994 introduction of sweeps, in which banks “swept” cash from checking accounts into savings accounts each night to take advantage of lower reserve requirements on the latter, has dramatically reversed. Uncertainty and a lack of confidence have led banks to accumulate huge quantities of excess reserves at the Fed rather than lending these funds out. This uncertainty has yet to be dispelled.

Download the pdf by clicking on the picture below

image

Nessun commento:

Posta un commento

Post in evidenza

The Great Taking - The Movie

David Webb exposes the system Central Bankers have in place to take everything from everyone Webb takes us on a 50-year journey of how the C...