giovedì 26 dicembre 2019

Currency and Bank Notes Act, 1914 (a very rare text)

1914 August 6th

 Currency and Bank Notes Act, 1914: ‘A Bill, To authorise the issue of Currency Notes, and to make provision with respect to the Note Issue of Banks’. 

Issued one day after Britain declared war on Germany, this act permitted the Government to print notes as legal tender in place of gold sovereigns and half-sovereigns. By withdrawing gold from internal circulation, this Act effectively suspended the gold standard and in practice allowed for an inflationary expansion of the money supply enabling the Government to print notes to cover its obligations. Consequently, the Act gave the Government, operating through the Bank of England, great latitude to the Bank of England in issuing notes beyond the limit authorised by law. The Royal Mint continued to mint gold sovereigns until 1917, although with the issuance of large amounts of paper money, gold coins were soon withdrawn from circulation. 

 ——— Be it enacted by the King’s most Excellent Majesty, by and with the advice and consent of the Lords Spiritual and Temporal, and Commons, in this present Parliament assembled, and by the authority of the same, as follows:

1 — 
 (1) The Treasury may, subject to the provisions of this Act, issue currency notes for one pound and for ten shillings, and those notes shall be current in the United Kingdom in the same manner and to the same extent and as fully as sovereigns and half-sovereigns are current and shall be legal tender in the United Kingdom for the payment of any amount.  

(2) Currency notes under this Act shall be in such form and of such design and printed from such plate and on such paper and be authenticated in such manner as may be directed by the Treasury.  

(3) The holder of a currency note shall be entitled to obtain on demand during office hours at the Bank of England payment for the note at its face value in gold coin, which is for the time being legal tender in the United Kingdom.  

(4) The Treasury may, subject to such conditions at to time, manner, and order of presentation as they think fit call in any currency notes under this Act on paying for those notes at their face value in gold. 

 (5) Currency notes under this Act shall be deemed to be bank notes within the meaning of the Forgery Act, 1913, and any other enactment relating to offences in respect of bank notes which is for the time being in force in any part of the British Islands, and to be valuable securities within the meaning of the Larceny Act, 1861, and any other law relating to stealing which is for the time being in force in any part of the British Islands, and to be current coin of the realm for the purpose of the Acts relating to truck and any other enactment. 

 (6) For the purpose of meeting immediate exigencies all postal orders issued either before or after the passing of this Act shall temporarily be current and legal tender in the United Kingdom in the same manner and to the same extent and as fully as current coins, and shall be legal tender in the United Kingdom for the payment of any amount.  
The holder of any such postal order shall be entitled to obtain on demand during office hours at the Bank of England payment for the postal order at its face value in any coin which is for the time being legal tender in the United Kingdom for the amount of the note.  
Provisos (b) and (c) to subsection (1) of section twenty-four of the Post Office Act, 1908, shall not apply to any such postal orders.  
This subsection shall have effect only until His Majesty by proclamation revokes the same, and any proclamation revoking this subsection may provide for the calling in or exchange of any postal orders affected thereby.  

2. Currency notes may be issued to such persons and in such manner as the Treasury direct, but the amount of any notes issued to any person shall, by virtue of this Act, and without registration or further assurance, be a floating charge in priority to all other charges, whether under statute or otherwise, on the assets of that person. 

 3. The governor and company of the Bank of England and any persons concerned in the management of any Scottish or Irish Bank of issue may, so far as temporarily authorised by the Treasury and subject to any conditions attached to that authority, issue notes in excess of any limit fixed by law; and those persons are hereby indemnified, freed, and discharged from any liability, penal or civil, in respect of any issue of notes beyond the amount fixed by law which has been made by them since the first day of August nineteen hundred and fourteen in pursuance of any authority of the Treasury or of any letter from the Chancellor of the Exchequer, and any proceedings taken to enforce any such liability shall be void.  

4. Any bank notes issued by a bank of issue in Scotland or Ireland shall be legal tender for a payment of any amount in Scotland or Ireland respectively, and any such bank of issue shall not be under any obligation to pay its notes on demand except at the head office of the bank, and may pay its notes, if thought fit, in currency notes issued under this Act: Provided that notes which are legal tender under this section shall not be legal tender for any payment by the head office of the bank by whom they are issued for the purpose of the payment of notes issued by that bank.  
 This section shall have effect only until His Majesty by proclamation revokes the same, and any proclamation revoking this section may provide for the calling in or exchange of notes affected thereby.  

5.— 
(1) In this Act, the expression “bank of issue” means any bank having power for the time being to issue bank notes.  
(2) This Act may be cited as the Currency and Bank Notes Act, 1914.  
(3) This Act shall apply to the Isle of Man as if it were part of the United Kingdom, but shall not apply to any other British possession. 

 ——— Source: Great Britain, Parliamentary Papers, House of Commons, 1914, 361, vol. 1. 

§§§§§§§§§§§§§§§§§§§§§§§<------->

An Act to amend the Currency and Bank Notes Act, 1914 [28th august 1914]

Be it enacted by the King's most Excellent Majesty, by and with the advice and consent of the Lords Spiritual and Temporal, and Commons, in this present Parliament assembled, and by the authority of the same, as follows:


1. The power of the Treasury to call in currency notes under subsection (4) of the section one of the Currency and Bank Notes Act, 1914, shall be extended so as to include a power to call in currency notes, on exchanging the notes so called in, for other notes of the same face value issued under that Act.


2. The Treasury may, if they think fit, instead of issuing any notes to any person, give to that person a certificate entitling him to the issue, on demand from the Treasury, of the notes mentioned in the certificate; and the notes covered by the certificate shall, for the purposes of section two of the Currency and Bank Notes Act, 1914, be deemed to be notes issued to that person.


3. This Act may be cited as the Currency and Bank Notes (Amendment) Act, 1914.
 

------Source: House of Commons, House of Commons parliamentary papers, 1914 (London: House of Commons, 1914), vol. 1, pp. 873-6.

mercoledì 25 dicembre 2019

Auditors and the Private Finance Initiative (PFI)

PRIVATE PARTY

Extract from Bean Counters: The Triumph of the Accountants and How They Broke Capitalism

Central to New Labour’s election victory was renouncing high taxes and committing to sound public finances. These twin new commitments were enshrined in a self-imposed limit on government debt. But the party had also distinguished itself from the Tories by promising to improve public services that had been starved of investment. This created a fiscal conundrum. How was the extra spending to be funded without extra borrowing? The answer was something called the private finance initiative (PFI), which had been devised by the previous government but used only to a limited extent for some road extensions and a couple of prisons. The new government would put all its infrastructure eggs in the PFI basket, no longer paying for major projects out of taxes or borrowings. Consortia of banks, construction companies and service providers would borrow the money, construct the school, hospital or other facility and then make it available to the relevant public service under a long-term agreement. The magic in the scheme was that the taxpayer’s commitment to pay fees for using the new infrastructure every year, typically for thirty years, would not usually count as government borrowing. The scheme would be ‘off the books’.

Under cautious government rules, such helpful accounting was strictly possible only if the taxpayer was not on the hook if the scheme went wrong. The Tories had accordingly insisted that the private companies bear all the risks of any deal, which had limited PFI’s appeal to the bankers and builders on whose involvement the scheme depended. So when he took office, anxious to deploy PFI for hospital- and school-building programmes, Gordon Brown set about making it more attractive to them. Under a special task force containing two consultants from Price Waterhouse and one from Coopers & Lybrand working on the all-important accounting, the rules were relaxed. 2

Private companies would be able to shoulder fewer risks, while the government would keep its essential off-the-books accounting. Not for the first – or last – time, the bean counters had written the rules of a game they would go on to play very profitably.

The other knotty problem was that, under a long-standing parliamentary principle, large projects could be signed only if they gave value for money. This was tricky when the price to be paid to the private PFI consortia had to include profits large enough to persuade them into lengthy deals and cover private borrowing costs, which were always higher than the government’s. PFI was inevitably far more expensive than the alternative of conventional government funding. To get over this hurdle, a series of spurious reductions would be applied to the sum of future PFI payments when comparing the cost of a proposed scheme with paying for it through government borrowing and taxation. Many were highly subjective, involving estimates of the likely costs of vague matters such as ‘operational risk’. Then there was an adjustment for ‘optimism bias’, on the soon-discredited assumption that traditional procurement ran significantly more over-budget than PFI. There was even a large discount for tax payments that the private companies operating PFI schemes would supposedly make but in reality did not. It was devised by KPMG at the same time as the firm was advising the PFI companies on how to avoid their tax liabilities. This usually involved treating the costs of building schools or hospitals not as an asset on the PFI company’s balance sheet but as an ongoing expense, which attracted greater tax relief. Many of the country’s largest new hospitals were thus taken off both the government’s and the PFI companies’ books, dispatched to an accounting fourth dimension. One Tory MP (and chartered accountant) taunted Gordon Brown with some justification that he had become the ‘Enron Chancellor’. 3

The fiddles achieved the desired result. Over Labour’s first two terms in government, more than 400 deals for infrastructure worth £25bn were signed (the figure now stands at about £60bn worth, costing £10bn a year for another generation). 4

The complex contracts required the services of financial consultants, almost always from KPMG, PwC, Deloitte or Ernst & Young, on each side. Public bodies such as NHS trusts or local education authorities, for whom each deal was a once-in-a-generation event, were especially dependent on their expert advice. The Big Four would ensure that their value-for-money calculations gave the ‘right’ answer and that they kept their scheme ‘off the books’. One accounting academic who advised the Treasury on PFI, later explained: ‘There became an industry in cosmetic presentation of projects.’ 5

A rich industry it was too, with fees for all advisers coming in at around £3m for an average contract, around half of which would typically go to one of the Big Four firms. 6

By 2014, the same academic reckoned that the Big Four had earned £1bn from the private finance initiative. Small wonder they had been so keen to push it in the first place.

Conflicts of interest proliferated, the bean counters often advising public bodies on signing deals with companies that were also their clients for auditing and consulting services. And with the government’s task force recommending ‘success fees’ for advisers, including the major accountancy firms represented on the task force, the incentive was to get the deal done. There is no trace of any advice that a scheme wouldn’t be such a smart idea. 7

Getting the contract through often involved blatant manipulation, with the cost of a PFI deal usually ending up just a few pounds better value than the publicly funded alternative. In one case reported by the National Audit Office public spending watchdog, a new £130m hospital at West Middlesex had at first appeared to be more expensive to build under PFI. But the trust’s adviser, KPMG, had convened a series of ‘risk workshops’ to identify some more convenient risks associated with the public sector alternative. Hey presto, the PFI deal came out slightly cheaper. 8

The accountancy firms naturally became highly protective of their new golden goose. When critics attacked the early hospital deals – on which financial engineering took precedence over design quality, and extra costs immediately led to fewer beds for the sick – New Labour’s friends at Arthur Andersen & Co. stepped in with a study, in 1999, concluding that PFI schemes came in cheaper than others. It was soon discredited, mainly because it ignored large cost escalations after schemes had been agreed but before they were signed. 9

The leading PFI consultant, PwC, rode to the rescue with another supposedly ‘independent’ report. It was no more than a summary of testimonials from officials who had signed PFI contracts and were not about to admit they had thrown the taxpayer’s money away. Yet it became an official endorsement. When Prime Minister Blair was confronted in Parliament in 2002 with PFI’s shortcomings, he simply referred his questioner to ‘the PricewaterhouseCoopers report on the PFI, which found that it was excellent value for money’. 10 It certainly was for the bean counters, who as so often were paraded as independent authorities on areas from which they were getting very rich.

Meanwhile, the holder of the national public purse strings, Gordon Brown, was ensuring that Whitehall’s biggest investment decisions would be taken by PFI consultants from the Big Four firms rather than civil servants who might be more circumspect. KPMG’s head of infrastructure, Dr Timothy Stone, a former physical chemist who moved into consulting through Arthur Andersen and was known by some as the ‘sage of PFI’, became especially powerful. He could be found variously in the Department of Health’s commercial directorate, at the education department advising on the schools rebuilding programme, on the government’s ‘sustainable procurement’ task force and as permanent adviser to the Ministry of Defence on the biggest PFI scheme of them all, a £10bn project for in-flight jet-refuelling aircraft. ‘I wear many hats,’ the KPMG man would later admit. 11

Special PFI units inside the key government departments across Whitehall were all handed to consultants on secondment from the Big Four. In 2005, PwC bean counter Richard Abadie took over the central Treasury PFI Unit for a couple of years, delivering a 30% growth in the number of deals signed. 12

A few years later, back running PwC’s private finance practice (and having been succeeded at the Treasury by a Deloitte bean counter), Abadie was summoned by a sceptical committee of MPs. Would he ‘be willing to submit some aggregate numbers for the amounts of money [PwC] have earned on PFI in this country over the last 10 years?’ asked one. ‘Probably not,’ replied Abadie. ‘I believe that is commercially confidential.’ 13
Just like the other accountants’ ramps, even if the public were paying a heavy price, PFI was a private affair.


DISASTER MANAGEMENT

In 2008, after a five-year delay, the jet-refuelling scheme on which KPMG’s many-hatted Dr Stone had advised eventually went ahead. It soon became clear that the 27-year Future Strategic Tanker Aircraft contract had lumbered the armed forces with overpriced planes that weren’t even fit for ‘high-threat areas’: something of a drawback in military aircraft. The fiasco prompted one of the National Audit Office’s most damning reports on a major public contract, complete with the ‘not value for money’ black spot. The deal, said the watchdog, had been struck ‘without a sound evaluation of alternative procurement routes to justify why the PFI route offered the best value for money’. 14
 Since KPMG’s top PFI man had been in charge, this wasn’t too surprising.

In 2010, the outcome was summed up by the chairman of Parliament’s public accounts committee at the time, Sir Edward Leigh. ‘By introducing a private finance element to the deal,’ he concluded, ‘the MoD managed to turn what should have been a relatively straightforward procurement into a bureaucratic nightmare.’ 15

Still, a ‘bureaucratic nightmare’ is a consultant’s dream, and with the taxpayer handing over £10m for ‘finance, tax and accounting advice’, once again the bean counters led by Dr Stone came out on top. Nor did the affair harm the head of the MoD’s PFI unit who had signed off the deal, Nick Prior. By the time the extent of the waste was exposed, he had stepped through the well-oiled revolving door between Whitehall and the PFI industry to be Deloitte’s ‘global head of infrastructure’. There he rejoices in the role of ‘lead client service partner’ for the Ministry of Defence. 16

Even with PFI and the big accountancy firms’ role in it largely discredited, the scheme remains another gift from the taxpayer that keeps on giving to the bean counters. When hospital trusts saddled with overpriced PFI contracts inevitably ran into trouble after a few years, the Big Four would be back on the scene selling remedies for the ill-effects of their own snake oil. By 2013, the biggest health PFI scheme, a £1.1bn redevelopment at St Bartholomew and Royal London, was eating up £120m a year of the trust’s budget, plunging it into a deficit of around £50m and forcing thousands of job cuts. In came PwC as ‘turnaround’ specialists, even though the same firm had advised the trust on signing the PFI deal in the first place seven years earlier. Back then, even the trust’s chairman had admitted: ‘If this was the private sector, you’d be in jail. This is what got Enron into trouble. It’s all off the balance sheet. It’s cloud-cuckoo land, Alice in Wonderland stuff.’ 17
Yet not only did PwC go on to earn fees for the remedial financial advice, they then sold the hospital a ‘sustainable operational efficiency and improvement programme’. While the hospital cut thousands of jobs, the firm was shortlisted – without irony – for a Management Consultancies Association award in the ‘performance improvement in the public sector’ category. 18

Across Britain, the bean counters continue to clean up from the financial mess left by PFI bills that will demand payment before doctors’, nurses’, teachers’ and armed forces personnel’s wages for another generation. In 2013, six years after PwC told Peterborough hospital that a £400m PFI scheme was ‘competitive, robust and demonstrate[s] value for money’, the public accounts committee labelled it ‘catastrophic’. By this time PwC was back in there earning £3m a year from telling the trust how to deal with the £45m annual deficit caused by the contract. 19

Up in Northumbria, Deloitte advised the trust running Hexham General Hospital on how to buy itself out of a financially ruinous PFI deal that KPMG had advised it on back in the late 1990s. So expensive had the contract turned out that the trust could pay the PFI company tens of millions of pounds in compensation and still save money. 20

PFI became a huge public sector money-spinner for the Big Four accountancy firms and played a key role in ensconcing them in Whitehall. Once inside, they began creating a more enduring legacy. It would go well beyond the bricks and mortar and into the transformation of public services themselves.


Notes:

2. The consultants on the PFI task force were Ben Prynn and David Goldstone from Price Waterhouse and Tony Whitehead from Coopers & Lybrand.

3. Hansard, 2 April 2003, Col. 285WH.

4. From PFI summary data published annually by HM Treasury.

5. Comments from Professor David Heald, Aberdeen University, in Radio 4 File on 4 programme ‘The Accountant Kings’, broadcast 4 March 2014.

6. Public Accounts Committee report, HM Treasury: Tendering and Benchmarking in PFI, 27 November 2007.

7. Treasury Taskforce Technical Note 3: How to Appoint and Manage Advisers to PFI Projects,
https://ppp.worldbank.org/public-private-partnership/sites/ppp.worldbank.org/files/documents/How%20to%20Appoint2017%20and%20Manage%20Advisers
accessed 9 March 2017.

8. The PFI Contract for the Redevelopment of West Middlesex University Hospital, National Audit Office, 21 November 2002.

9. Professor Allyson Pollock, then of the Centre for International Public Health Policy at the University of Edinburgh, produced a number of papers taking apart the ‘evidence’ of those linked to PFI schemes. A good summary of the flaws of the Arthur Andersen report can be found in her evidence to Parliament’s Health Select Committee on 14 April 2000, available at
http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/cm200102/cmselect/cmhealth/308/308ap30.htm; accessed on 16 September 2016.

10. Hansard, 30 January 2002, Col. 286.

11. Evidence of Dr Timothy Stone to House of Lords Economic Affairs Committee inquiry into Private Finance Projects and Off Balance Sheet Debts, 13 October 2009.

12. Based on 47 deals signed in 2004/5 and 61 signed in 2007/8, data from HM Treasury ‘current projects’ dataset.

13. Evidence to House of Commons Treasury Select Committee on Private Finance Initiative, 14 June 2011.

14. ‘Delivering the Multi-role Tanker Aircraft Capability’, National Audit Office, 30 March 2010.

15. BBC report, 30 March 2010, http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/uk/8593788.stm.

16. Nick Prior, LinkedIn profile, accessed 16 September 2016.

17. Reported in Andrew Hankinson, ‘NHS Boss Dubs PFI “Alice in Wonderland stuff”’, Construction News, 22 September 2005, and in Private Eye magazine, issue 1200, December 2007.

18. https://www.mca.org.uk/library/documents/PI_Pub_-_PwC_with_Barts_NHS.pdf.

19. Public Accounts Committee report, Hinchingbrooke Health Care NHS Trust, Peterborough and Stamford Hospitals NHS Foundation Trust, 7 February 2013. The background to the 2007 signing of the contract given in report by Caroline Molloy on Open Democracy website, 19 September 2013, https://www.opendemocracy.net/ournhs/caroline-molloy/peterborough-hospital-nhs-and-britains-privatisation-racket; accessed 18 September 2016.

20. Gill Plumber and Sarah Neville, ‘NHS Trust Becomes First to Buy out its PFI Contract’, Financial Times, 1 October 2014.

martedì 24 dicembre 2019

UK: The first government banknotes

The first government banknotes

Source: https://www.rbsremembers.com/remembers/banking-in-wartime/supporting-the-nation/the-first-government-banknotes.html

Treasury-issue £1 note, also known as a 'Bradbury', 1917

At the outbreak of war in August 1914, one of the government’s first priorities was to withdraw gold from the circulating economy so that it could be put towards the national war effort. Moreover, hoarding of gold and silver coin was widespread, impeding normal small payments. To ensure that people still had cash in their tills and pockets, the government needed to introduce paper money instead.
In Scotland banknotes were already widely used, but in England and Wales the picture was very different. The Bank of England issued notes for values of £5 and up, but this was a large sum of money, comparable to more than £400 today. Most people never saw or used banknotes at all.
In order to replace gold coins effectively, a large supply of notes had to be made available for values of £1 and 10 shillings (that is, half a pound). The Bank of England could not prepare and print the required number of notes quickly enough, so the government took the unprecedented step of deciding to issue the notes itself. They would be called Treasury notes or, unofficially, 'Bradburys', after the signature they bore of Sir John Bradbury, permanent secretary to the Treasury. They would be legal tender, meaning that they had to be accepted when offered in payment of a debt; the creditor couldn’t hold out for gold.
Designs were drawn up over the weekend of 1-2 August 1914. They were delivered to the printer on Tuesday 4 August, the day Britain entered the war. The engraved vignette was borrowed from an existing one at the Royal Mint, and the notes were printed on postage stamp paper – the only ready supply available at the time. After two days of round-the-clock printing, £2.5m of new £1 notes were distributed to banks on Thursday 6 August 1914, ready for when they reopened on Friday. The £1 notes got them through the immediate crisis, and the 10s notes – useful for smaller transactions – were ready a week later.
The great haste with which the notes were prepared was necessary in the immediate crisis, but led to subsequent problems for anyone handling cash, including bank clerks. For one thing, the notes were small, measuring less than 13x7cm – smaller than a modern £5 note. In contrast, a Bank of England £5 at that time was about the size of a paperback book cover. In Parliament one MP likened them to ‘lottery tickets’. Their small size made them difficult to handle. One Ulster Bank clerk complained, ‘the operation of dealing with a large number of 10/- notes is a severe test even to a sleight-of-hand artist. In short the notes are too small for rapid manipulation.’
There were also problems with forgery. The hasty design had made it impossible to incorporate effective anti-counterfeiting measures. Worse still, in England and Wales people were not used to handling banknotes, so didn’t know how to spot a fake. Furthermore, people were moving around the country more than in peacetime. Shopkeepers and bank clerks found themselves dealing with strangers, making it easier for forgers to pass their work into circulation unnoticed.
‘Forgeries’ were not always the result of criminal intent. In 1915, there was a flurry of cases of companies issuing advertising flyers in the style of treasury notes. Meant as eye-catching topical references, some were very similar to the notes they copied, and actually found their way into circulation, either deliberately or by accident.
Despite the difficulties, Treasury notes played a vital role in keeping the economy moving during the First World War. For the first time in England and Wales, paper money became normal currency, used by ordinary people. After the war, its use continued. Treasury notes were issued until 1928, and thereafter the Bank of England took over responsibility for issuing £1 and 10s notes. 

domenica 22 dicembre 2019

The Democratic People’s Republic of U.S. Monetary Policy


Argument

The Democratic People’s Republic of U.S. Monetary Policy

Congress is outsourcing more and more policymaking to the Federal Reserve.

$100 notes are printed at the U.S. Bureau of Engraving and Printing in Washington, D.C., on May 20, 2013.
$100 notes are printed at the U.S. Bureau of Engraving and Printing in Washington, D.C., on May 20, 2013. Mark Wilson/Getty Images
In a post-Great Recession world, monetary policy just looks different. For one thing, central bank independence is dead—but the U.S. Congress doesn’t know it yet. We could argue for hours, or days, about whether it ever really existed or when exactly it died, but suffice to say that the moment quantitative easing started, the Federal Reserve stepped out of its well-defined monetary box, and independence was no more. Central bankers know it: In a recent survey, 61 percent of former central bankers surveyed from around the world predicted that central banks would be less independent in the future.

The U.S. Congress has not acknowledged this reality. Members of Congress depend on the doctrine of central bank independence to keep the dirty business of monetary policy off their hands. The question is whether Congress will continue to ignore reality and let the Fed take on more power—and increasingly fiscal rather than just monetary—over the economy or whether it will choose to step in, reassert its political power, and get more involved. Most important of all is a question no one seems willing to ask: What might the answer to this question say about the state of U.S. democracy?

The Fed’s policymaking power comes from its congressional mandate “to promote effectively the goals of maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates.” That’s a pretty vague mandate. Imagine the range of policies that might influence employment, price stability, and interest rates: job creation, education, health care, climate change, electoral politics, the list goes on. Prior to the 2008 financial crisis, the Fed’s delegated powers were restricted by a set of informal limitations. Namely, the Fed, an independent central bank populated by experts, would execute monetary policy according to internationally accepted best practices. But the crisis exploded the conventional consensus on best practices and, in so doing, broke the restrictions on the Fed’s power. That’s a problem. As Paul Tucker, a former deputy governor of the Bank of England, wrote in 2018, without clarity on the limits of their power, central bankers would “be incentivized to do whatever is needed to deliver their mandate, however far that reaches into fiscal territory.”
One of the initiatives they tried during the financial crisis was quantitative easing. After conventional approaches, like manipulating the short-term interest rate, proved insufficient, they turned to QE. QE is a form of large-scale asset purchase in which the Fed buys a huge number of longer-term government-backed securities using newly created central bank reserves in an effort to change the contours of the market. Although the world is a decade past the crisis, central banks have struggled to restore conventional policy. The post-2008 economy is not like the pre-2008 economy. In particular, policymakers are staring down the barrel of persistently low natural real interest rates and the realization that inflation seems to be determined more by inflation expectations than by real economic slack. The upshot of this new economic environment is that, from now on, conventional monetary policy will not be sufficient to maintain price stability.
In June, the Fed convened a conference to address the problem. In his opening remarks, Federal Reserve Chair Jerome Powell posed three guiding questions that can be summed up in one: How can the Federal Reserve continue to reach its stated aims in the face of this new economic environment, taking existing governance structures as given? He went on to suggest an answer: “Perhaps it is time to retire the term ‘unconventional’ when referring to tools that were used in the crisis.” This was more or less the prevailing theme of the entire conference: Make the unconventional conventional. In other words, quantitative easing will be part of the new normal. That’s already started to happen. Take one example: The New York Fed recently implemented large repurchase agreement operations, essentially launching a targeted version of QE to prevent the collapse of one far-away corner of the financial markets with a liquidity problem. This has gone largely unnoticed in the public domain.
There are two ways to interpret the Fed’s so-called normalization of the abnormal.
There are two ways to interpret the Fed’s so-called normalization of the abnormal.
It is either a power grab or an administrative agency doing its best to fulfill its congressional mandate in a new economic environment. In reality, it is probably both. The fact that such blatant overreach is necessary should perhaps tell us something about the job itself, the state of the economy, and the state of the U.S. democracy. Under either interpretation, Congress is shirking its responsibility to govern the macroeconomy by allowing the Fed to redraw the boundaries of its own policy jurisdiction.

Money is the stuff of our collective life. It is what binds us together as citizens; it determines who is permitted to do what in society, what society values, what it wishes to create, and much more. Money represents our social, economic, and political interdependence. The central bank is not the only institution that creates money. Banks do. Every time a bank extends credit, it creates money. The Fed’s power over the money supply, then, is not all about choosing how many dollars to print. In large part it comes from the Fed’s ability to incentivize banks to extend more or less credit, on easier or more stringent terms. Right now, the Fed’s monetary authority—the Federal Open Market Committee—is made up of only 10 people: All are white, none are elected.

Both conventional and unconventional monetary policy involve open market operations, in which the Fed executes monetary policy by buying or selling assets on the so-called open market. The use of the term “open market” here is a bit misleading. Whenever the Fed buys and sells Treasurys in order to execute monetary policy, it interacts with a predetermined set of primary dealers. There are about 20 designated primary dealers at any given time. The list changes fairly regularly and is not limited to U.S.-owned financial institutions. Today’s primary dealers include BNP Paribas; Barclays; Bank of Nova Scotia, New York Agency; BofA Securities; Citigroup Global Markets; and Goldman Sachs, to name a few.

The expectation is that the Fed’s buying and selling Treasurys to and from primary dealers will stimulate the entire economy. The enormous asset purchases the Fed made from primary dealers as part of QE were meant to encourage investors to put their money in riskier assets and thereby reduce the cost of borrowing across the economy. It was up to the investors, of course, to decide which assets to invest in, when, how much, and why. In sum, trickle-down economics is alive and well in U.S. monetary policy.
To see how, consider that when the United States creates new money, whether through QE or more conventional channels, it disseminates that money through private financial institutions run by individuals who are extremely rich and are explicitly profit-seeking. These financial institutions decide how much money to create, whom to extend credit to, and on what terms. These same private financial institutions have a history of disseminating credit to the rest of the population in a highly lopsided manner. The U.S. approach to governing money leaves much to be desired. The public does not decide democratically what it values or wishes to create—instead, it lets Fed officials and private financial institutions do that on its behalf.

The Fed’s recent efforts to normalize QE will only make things worse. The locus of power over monetary policy is drifting further and further away from the people and their elected representatives. This poses a threat to U.S. democracy. That should be no surprise, really, because it means unelected bureaucrats taking on more power and responsibility while elected officials continue to shirk.

Perhaps this system is the best option. In today’s world, one must at least entertain the idea that a good bureaucratic policy is better than a bad democratic one. From one vantage point, technocratic monetary policy has come to the United States’ rescue, especially when contrasted with the Trump administration’s abysmal policies on the environment, taxes, the provision of public goods, and more. The Fed, for its part, is starting to focus more and more on the fight against inequality, and elsewhere in the world central banks are beginning to turn their attention to addressing climate change. To steal a phrase from a recent opinion piece in the New York Times, civil servants are sexy—“they are heroes of the resistance.”

The idea of the heroic bureaucrat is not new in monetary policy, a sector dominated by the idea that expert technocrats can implement optimal policy. As four former Fed chairs wrote in a piece in the Wall Street Journal this past August, “History, both here and abroad, has shown repeatedly … that an economy is strongest and functions best when the central bank acts independently of short-term political pressures and relies solely on sound economic principles and data.”

Good technocratic monetary policy, in other words, is not an opportunity to be missed. It is a unicorn in economic theory: a free lunch. In the short run, according to conventional theory, monetary policy can be used to stabilize aggregate demand to meet aggregate supply, thereby dampening business cycles and achieving price stability. In the long run, monetary policy is nothing more than deciding the price of money, thereby influencing how much money is in the system—if bread costs $1 or $100. Monetary policy is assumed to have no lasting effect on output or unemployment and, thus, no real cost. The conventional view can be summed up as follows: Fiscal policy is what shapes the real economy; monetary policy merely matches it. Or as one Bloomberg commentator put it, “the point of the Fed is to read and react.”

This is all very neat and tidy, but what does monetary policy acting only to match the real economy actually look like? It’s more complicated than you might think. Take the example of U.S. President Donald Trump’s recent war with the Fed. Trump is not only berating the Fed on Twitter, he is also creating an economic world in which his coveted lower interest rates actually make sense. His trade war with China has contributed to an economic environment in which the Fed, relying “solely on sound economic principles and data,” would likely lower rates. Trump has contributed to the development of an economic situation in which, on the numbers alone, it makes sense for the Fed to what exactly what Trump demands it does: lower rates.

In such a situation, what should the Fed do? Should it comply? Or should the Fed refuse to play along with the president in pursuit of longer-term price stability—that is, not lower rates to avoid a trade-induced economic disaster? The latter option was the forceful suggestion of former New York Fed President and CEO William Dudley in a now-infamous Bloomberg op-ed. Dudley went on to suggest, “There’s even an argument that the election itself falls within the Fed’s purview. After all, Trump’s reelection arguably presents a threat to the U.S. and global economy.” Let’s be clear about what this former Federal Open Market Committee member is suggesting: The Federal Reserve, the independent central bank of the United States, should interfere in the nation’s general election.
Let’s be clear about what this former Federal Open Market Committee member is suggesting: The Federal Reserve, the independent central bank of the United States, should interfere in the nation’s general election.
Here we have a direct conflict between good bureaucracy and bad democracy—the good bureaucrats correcting for bad democratic impulses. As much as observers fretted over the idea that a foreign power could, and had, interfered with the integrity of the U.S. election system, fewer were outraged by the idea of the Fed interfering. Sure, Russia is a foreign power, and the Fed is a U.S. institution, but when it comes to the integrity of the democratic system, that distinction should not really matter. What is the difference, after all, between a sexy bureaucrat and a benevolent dictator? Both are unelected officials who some set of observers think are doing the right thing.

To be sure, it is inevitable that some policymaking power will be delegated to bureaucrats. There will always be unelected officials making policy decisions that influence citizens’ lives. This is no threat to democracy, so long as ultimate political power remains with the people and their elected representatives. But if those officials delegate immense power, in perpetuity, with no intention of ever reevaluating the terms and conditions of delegation, then delegated power starts to look increasingly like usurped power. The unelected bureaucrat starts to look more like a dictator—benevolent or not.

Today’s political environment is forcing voters to decide how much they really care about democracy as such. To properly answer this question, it is important to separate out the following two questions: Who should decide on policy? And which policies should be implemented? For those who believe that democracy is of fundamental importance, the who question must be prior to the which matter. In today’s political environment, that means swallowing some awful policies—the Muslim travel ban, the 2017 tax cuts, putting children in cages, and much more.

Given the fundamental importance of democracy, Congress should take its fingers out of its ears and reassert its political power over monetary policy. Some might like to see U.S. monetary policy used to fight inequality, the perils of climate change, and existing biases in credit allocation under the watchful eye of Congress. Others might want it to promote political goals such as building a wall on the southern border. In a world in which Congress wakes up and governs the economy, rather than leaving it to the Fed, selecting from among those policies would ultimately be in the hands of the people. That is a risk those who believe in democracy should be willing to take. If the people are allowed to choose only when they make the right choices, then the United States would not be a democracy. It would be something more like the Democratic People’s Republic of U.S. Monetary Policy.


Leah Downey is a PhD candidate in the Harvard Government department and a graduate fellow at the E. J. Safra Center for Ethics.

Against Economics

Against Economics

Men’s Retreat, 2005; painting by Dana Schutz
Dana Schutz/Petzel, New York CityDana Schutz: Men’s Retreat, 2005
There is a growing feeling, among those who have the responsibility of managing large economies, that the discipline of economics is no longer fit for purpose. It is beginning to look like a science designed to solve problems that no longer exist.

A good example is the obsession with inflation. Economists still teach their students that the primary economic role of government—many would insist, its only really proper economic role—is to guarantee price stability. We must be constantly vigilant over the dangers of inflation. For governments to simply print money is therefore inherently sinful. If, however, inflation is kept at bay through the coordinated action of government and central bankers, the market should find its “natural rate of unemployment,” and investors, taking advantage of clear price signals, should be able to ensure healthy growth. These assumptions came with the monetarism of the 1980s, the idea that government should restrict itself to managing the money supply, and by the 1990s had come to be accepted as such elementary common sense that pretty much all political debate had to set out from a ritual acknowledgment of the perils of government spending. This continues to be the case, despite the fact that, since the 2008 recession, central banks have been printing money frantically in an attempt to create inflation and compel the rich to do something useful with their money, and have been largely unsuccessful in both endeavors.
We now live in a different economic universe than we did before the crash. Falling unemployment no longer drives up wages. Printing money does not cause inflation. Yet the language of public debate, and the wisdom conveyed in economic textbooks, remain almost entirely unchanged.

One expects a certain institutional lag. Mainstream economists nowadays might not be particularly good at predicting financial crashes, facilitating general prosperity, or coming up with models for preventing climate change, but when it comes to establishing themselves in positions of intellectual authority, unaffected by such failings, their success is unparalleled. One would have to look at the history of religions to find anything like it. To this day, economics continues to be taught not as a story of arguments—not, like any other social science, as a welter of often warring theoretical perspectives—but rather as something more like physics, the gradual realization of universal, unimpeachable mathematical truths. “Heterodox” theories of economics do, of course, exist (institutionalist, Marxist, feminist, “Austrian,” post-Keynesian…), but their exponents have been almost completely locked out of what are considered “serious” departments, and even outright rebellions by economics students (from the post-autistic economics movement in France to post-crash economics in Britain) have largely failed to force them into the core curriculum.
As a result, heterodox economists continue to be treated as just a step or two away from crackpots, despite the fact that they often have a much better record of predicting real-world economic events. What’s more, the basic psychological assumptions on which mainstream (neoclassical) economics is based—though they have long since been disproved by actual psychologists—have colonized the rest of the academy, and have had a profound impact on popular understandings of the world.

Nowhere is this divide between public debate and economic reality more dramatic than in Britain, which is perhaps why it appears to be the first country where something is beginning to crack. It was center-left New Labour that presided over the pre-crash bubble, and voters’ throw-the-bastards-out reaction brought a series of Conservative governments that soon discovered that a rhetoric of austerity—the Churchillian evocation of common sacrifice for the public good—played well with the British public, allowing them to win broad popular acceptance for policies designed to pare down what little remained of the British welfare state and redistribute resources upward, toward the rich. “There is no magic money tree,” as Theresa May put it during the snap election of 2017—virtually the only memorable line from one of the most lackluster campaigns in British history. The phrase has been repeated endlessly in the media, whenever someone asks why the UK is the only country in Western Europe that charges university tuition, or whether it is really necessary to have quite so many people sleeping on the streets.

The truly extraordinary thing about May’s phrase is that it isn’t true. There are plenty of magic money trees in Britain, as there are in any developed economy. They are called “banks.” Since modern money is simply credit, banks can and do create money literally out of nothing, simply by making loans. Almost all of the money circulating in Britain at the moment is bank-created in this way. Not only is the public largely unaware of this, but a recent survey by the British research group Positive Money discovered that an astounding 85 percent of members of Parliament had no idea where money really came from (most appeared to be under the impression that it was produced by the Royal Mint).
Economists, for obvious reasons, can’t be completely oblivious to the role of banks, but they have spent much of the twentieth century arguing about what actually happens when someone applies for a loan. One school insists that banks transfer existing funds from their reserves, another that they produce new money, but only on the basis of a multiplier effect (so that your car loan can still be seen as ultimately rooted in some retired grandmother’s pension fund). Only a minority—mostly heterodox economists, post-Keynesians, and modern money theorists—uphold what is called the “credit creation theory of banking”: that bankers simply wave a magic wand and make the money appear, secure in the confidence that even if they hand a client a credit for $1 million, ultimately the recipient will put it back in the bank again, so that, across the system as a whole, credits and debts will cancel out. Rather than loans being based in deposits, in this view, deposits themselves were the result of loans.
The one thing it never seemed to occur to anyone to do was to get a job at a bank, and find out what actually happens when someone asks to borrow money. In 2014 a German economist named Richard Werner did exactly that, and discovered that, in fact, loan officers do not check their existing funds, reserves, or anything else. They simply create money out of thin air, or, as he preferred to put it, “fairy dust.”

That year also appears to have been when elements in Britain’s notoriously independent civil service decided that enough was enough. The question of money creation became a critical bone of contention. The overwhelming majority of even mainstream economists in the UK had long since rejected austerity as counterproductive (which, predictably, had almost no impact on public debate). But at a certain point, demanding that the technocrats charged with running the system base all policy decisions on false assumptions about something as elementary as the nature of money becomes a little like demanding that architects proceed on the understanding that the square root of 47 is actually π. Architects are aware that buildings would start falling down. People would die.

Before long, the Bank of England (the British equivalent of the Federal Reserve, whose economists are most free to speak their minds since they are not formally part of the government) rolled out an elaborate official report called “Money Creation in the Modern Economy,” replete with videos and animations, making the same point: existing economics textbooks, and particularly the reigning monetarist orthodoxy, are wrong. The heterodox economists are right. Private banks create money. Central banks like the Bank of England create money as well, but monetarists are entirely wrong to insist that their proper function is to control the money supply. In fact, central banks do not in any sense control the money supply; their main function is to set the interest rate—to determine how much private banks can charge for the money they create. Almost all public debate on these subjects is therefore based on false premises. For example, if what the Bank of England was saying were true, government borrowing didn’t divert funds from the private sector; it created entirely new money that had not existed before.

One might have imagined that such an admission would create something of a splash, and in certain restricted circles, it did. Central banks in Norway, Switzerland, and Germany quickly put out similar papers. Back in the UK, the immediate media response was simply silence. The Bank of England report has never, to my knowledge, been so much as mentioned on the BBC or any other TV news outlet. Newspaper columnists continued to write as if monetarism was self-evidently correct. Politicians continued to be grilled about where they would find the cash for social programs. It was as if a kind of entente cordiale had been established, in which the technocrats would be allowed to live in one theoretical universe, while politicians and news commentators would continue to exist in an entirely different one.

Still, there are signs that this arrangement is temporary. England—and the Bank of England in particular—prides itself on being a bellwether for global economic trends. Monetarism itself got its launch into intellectual respectability in the 1970s after having been embraced by Bank of England economists. From there it was ultimately adopted by the insurgent Thatcher regime, and only after that by Ronald Reagan in the United States, and it was subsequently exported almost everywhere else.

It is possible that a similar pattern is reproducing itself today. In 2015, a year after the appearance of the Bank of England report, the Labour Party for the first time allowed open elections for its leadership, and the left wing of the party, under Jeremy Corbyn and now shadow chancellor of the exchequer John McDonnell, took hold of the reins of power. At the time, the Labour left were considered even more marginal extremists than was Thatcher’s wing of the Conservative Party in 1975; it is also (despite the media’s constant efforts to paint them as unreconstructed 1970s socialists) the only major political group in the UK that has been open to new economic ideas. While pretty much the entire political establishment has been spending most of its time these last few years screaming at one another about Brexit, McDonnell’s office—and Labour youth support groups—have been holding workshops and floating policy initiatives on everything from a four-day workweek and universal basic income to a Green Industrial Revolution and “Fully Automated Luxury Communism,” and inviting heterodox economists to take part in popular education initiatives aimed at transforming conceptions of how the economy really works. Corbynism has faced near-histrionic opposition from virtually all sectors of the political establishment, but it would be unwise to ignore the possibility that something historic is afoot.

One sign that something historically new has indeed appeared is if scholars begin reading the past in a new light. Accordingly, one of the most significant books to come out of the UK in recent years would have to be Robert Skidelsky’s Money and Government: The Past and Future of Economics. Ostensibly an attempt to answer the question of why mainstream economics rendered itself so useless in the years immediately before and after the crisis of 2008, it is really an attempt to retell the history of the economic discipline through a consideration of the two things—money and government—that most economists least like to talk about.
Robert Skidelsky, 2013
Richard Saker/Contour by Getty Images Robert Skidelsky, London, 2013
Skidelsky is well positioned to tell this story. He embodies a uniquely English type: the gentle maverick, so firmly ensconced in the establishment that it never occurs to him that he might not be able to say exactly what he thinks, and whose views are tolerated by the rest of the establishment precisely for that reason. Born in Manchuria, trained at Oxford, professor of political economy at Warwick, Skidelsky is best known as the author of the definitive, three-volume biography of John Maynard Keynes, and has for the last three decades sat in the House of Lords as Baron of Tilton, affiliated at different times with a variety of political parties, and sometimes none at all. During the early Blair years, he was a Conservative, and even served as opposition spokesman on economic matters in the upper chamber; currently he’s a cross-bench independent, broadly aligned with left Labour. In other words, he follows his own flag. Usually, it’s an interesting flag. Over the last several years, Skidelsky has been taking advantage of his position in the world’s most elite legislative body to hold a series of high-level seminars on the reformation of the economic discipline; this book is, in a sense, the first major product of these endeavors.

What it reveals is an endless war between two broad theoretical perspectives in which the same side always seems to win—for reasons that rarely have anything to do with either theoretical sophistication or greater predictive power. The crux of the argument always seems to turn on the nature of money. Is money best conceived of as a physical commodity, a precious substance used to facilitate exchange, or is it better to see money primarily as a credit, a bookkeeping method or circulating IOU—in any case, a social arrangement? This is an argument that has been going on in some form for thousands of years. What we call “money” is always a mixture of both, and, as I myself noted in Debt (2011), the center of gravity between the two tends to shift back and forth over time. In the Middle Ages everyday transactions across Eurasia were typically conducted by means of credit, and money was assumed to be an abstraction. It was the rise of global European empires in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries, and the corresponding flood of gold and silver looted from the Americas, that really shifted perceptions. Historically, the feeling that bullion actually is money tends to mark periods of generalized violence, mass slavery, and predatory standing armies—which for most of the world was precisely how the Spanish, Portuguese, Dutch, French, and British empires were experienced. One important theoretical innovation that these new bullion-based theories of money allowed was, as Skidelsky notes, what has come to be called the quantity theory of money (usually referred to in textbooks—since economists take endless delight in abbreviations—as QTM).

The QTM argument was first put forward by a French lawyer named Jean Bodin, during a debate over the cause of the sharp, destablizing price inflation that immediately followed the Iberian conquest of the Americas. Bodin argued that the inflation was a simple matter of supply and demand: the enormous influx of gold and silver from the Spanish colonies was cheapening the value of money in Europe. The basic principle would no doubt have seemed a matter of common sense to anyone with experience of commerce at the time, but it turns out to have been based on a series of false assumptions. For one thing, most of the gold and silver extracted from Mexico and Peru did not end up in Europe at all, and certainly wasn’t coined into money. Most of it was transported directly to China and India (to buy spices, silks, calicoes, and other “oriental luxuries”), and insofar as it had inflationary effects back home, it was on the basis of speculative bonds of one sort or another. This almost always turns out to be true when QTM is applied: it seems self-evident, but only if you leave most of the critical factors out.

In the case of the sixteenth-century price inflation, for instance, once one takes account of credit, hoarding, and speculation—not to mention increased rates of economic activity, investment in new technology, and wage levels (which, in turn, have a lot to do with the relative power of workers and employers, creditors and debtors)—it becomes impossible to say for certain which is the deciding factor: whether the money supply drives prices, or prices drive the money supply. Technically, this comes down to a choice between what are called exogenous and endogenous theories of money. Should money be treated as an outside factor, like all those Spanish dubloons supposedly sweeping into Antwerp, Dublin, and Genoa in the days of Philip II, or should it be imagined primarily as a product of economic activity itself, mined, minted, and put into circulation, or more often, created as credit instruments such as loans, in order to meet a demand—which would, of course, mean that the roots of inflation lie elsewhere?

To put it bluntly: QTM is obviously wrong. Doubling the amount of gold in a country will have no effect on the price of cheese if you give all the gold to rich people and they just bury it in their yards, or use it to make gold-plated submarines (this is, incidentally, why quantitative easing, the strategy of buying long-term government bonds to put money into circulation, did not work either). What actually matters is spending.

Nonetheless, from Bodin’s time to the present, almost every time there was a major policy debate, the QTM advocates won. In England, the pattern was set in 1696, just after the creation of the Bank of England, with an argument over wartime inflation between Treasury Secretary William Lowndes, Sir Isaac Newton (then warden of the mint), and the philosopher John Locke. Newton had agreed with the Treasury that silver coins had to be officially devalued to prevent a deflationary collapse; Locke took an extreme monetarist position, arguing that the government should be limited to guaranteeing the value of property (including coins) and that tinkering would confuse investors and defraud creditors. Locke won. The result was deflationary collapse. A sharp tightening of the money supply created an abrupt economic contraction that threw hundreds of thousands out of work and created mass penury, riots, and hunger. The government quickly moved to moderate the policy (first by allowing banks to monetize government war debts in the form of bank notes, and eventually by moving off the silver standard entirely), but in its official rhetoric, Locke’s small-government, pro-creditor, hard-money ideology became the grounds of all further political debate.

According to Skidelsky, the pattern was to repeat itself again and again, in 1797, the 1840s, the 1890s, and, ultimately, the late 1970s and early 1980s, with Thatcher and Reagan’s (in each case brief) adoption of monetarism. Always we see the same sequence of events:
(1) The government adopts hard-money policies as a matter of principle.
(2) Disaster ensues.
(3) The government quietly abandons hard-money policies.
(4) The economy recovers.
(5) Hard-money philosophy nonetheless becomes, or is reinforced as, simple universal common sense.
How was it possible to justify such a remarkable string of failures? Here a lot of the blame, according to Skidelsky, can be laid at the feet of the Scottish philosopher David Hume. An early advocate of QTM, Hume was also the first to introduce the notion that short-term shocks—such as Locke produced—would create long-term benefits if they had the effect of unleashing the self-regulating powers of the market:
Ever since Hume, economists have distinguished between the short-run and the long-run effects of economic change, including the effects of policy interventions. The distinction has served to protect the theory of equilibrium, by enabling it to be stated in a form which took some account of reality. In economics, the short-run now typically stands for the period during which a market (or an economy of markets) temporarily deviates from its long-term equilibrium position under the impact of some “shock,” like a pendulum temporarily dislodged from a position of rest. This way of thinking suggests that governments should leave it to markets to discover their natural equilibrium positions. Government interventions to “correct” deviations will only add extra layers of delusion to the original one.
There is a logical flaw to any such theory: there’s no possible way to disprove it. The premise that markets will always right themselves in the end can only be tested if one has a commonly agreed definition of when the “end” is; but for economists, that definition turns out to be “however long it takes to reach a point where I can say the economy has returned to equilibrium.” (In the same way, statements like “the barbarians always win in the end” or “truth always prevails” cannot be proved wrong, since in practice they just mean “whenever barbarians win, or truth prevails, I shall declare the story over.”)

At this point, all the pieces were in place: tight-money policies (which benefited creditors and the wealthy) could be justified as “harsh medicine” to clear up price-signals so the market could return to a healthy state of long-run balance. In describing how all this came about, Skidelsky is providing us with a worthy extension of a history Karl Polanyi first began to map out in the 1940s: the story of how supposedly self-regulating national markets were the product of careful social engineering. Part of that involved creating government policies self-consciously designed to inspire resentment of “big government.” Skidelsky writes:
A crucial innovation was income tax, first levied in 1814, and renewed by [Prime Minister Robert] Peel in 1842. By 1911–14, this had become the principal source of government revenue. Income tax had the double benefit of giving the British state a secure revenue base, and aligning voters’ interests with cheap government, since only direct taxpayers had the vote…. “Fiscal probity,” under Gladstone, “became the new morality.”
In fact, there’s absolutely no reason a modern state should fund itself primarily by appropriating a proportion of each citizen’s earnings. There are plenty of other ways to go about it. Many—such as land, wealth, commercial, or consumer taxes (any of which can be made more or less progressive)—are considerably more efficient, since creating a bureaucratic apparatus capable of monitoring citizens’ personal affairs to the degree required by an income tax system is itself enormously expensive. But this misses the real point: income tax is supposed to be intrusive and exasperating. It is meant to feel at least a little bit unfair. Like so much of classical liberalism (and contemporary neoliberalism), it is an ingenious political sleight of hand—an expansion of the bureaucratic state that also allows its leaders to pretend to advocate for small government.

The one major exception to this pattern was the mid-twentieth century, what has come to be remembered as the Keynesian age. It was a period in which those running capitalist democracies, spooked by the Russian Revolution and the prospect of the mass rebellion of their own working classes, allowed unprecedented levels of redistribution—which, in turn, led to the most generalized material prosperity in human history. The story of the Keynesian revolution of the 1930s, and the neoclassical counterrevolution of the 1970s, has been told innumerable times, but Skidelsky gives the reader a fresh sense of the underlying conflict.
Wall Street, 2008
Christopher Anderson/Magnum Photos - Wall Street, 2008
Keynes himself was staunchly anti-Communist, but largely because he felt that capitalism was more likely to drive rapid technological advance that would largely eliminate the need for material labor. He wished for full employment not because he thought work was good, but because he ultimately wished to do away with work, envisioning a society in which technology would render human labor obsolete. In other words, he assumed that the ground was always shifting under the analysts’ feet; the object of any social science was inherently unstable. Max Weber, for similar reasons, argued that it would never be possible for social scientists to come up with anything remotely like the laws of physics, because by the time they had come anywhere near to gathering enough information, society itself, and what analysts felt was important to know about it, would have changed so much that the information would be irrelevant. Keynes’s opponents, on the other hand, were determined to root their arguments in just such universal principles.

It’s difficult for outsiders to see what was really at stake here, because the argument has come to be recounted as a technical dispute between the roles of micro- and macroeconomics. Keynesians insisted that the former is appropriate to studying the behavior of individual households or firms, trying to optimize their advantage in the marketplace, but that as soon as one begins to look at national economies, one is moving to an entirely different level of complexity, where different sorts of laws apply. Just as it is impossible to understand the mating habits of an aardvark by analyzing all the chemical reactions in their cells, so patterns of trade, investment, or the fluctuations of interest or employment rates were not simply the aggregate of all the microtransactions that seemed to make them up. The patterns had, as philosophers of science would put it, “emergent properties.” Obviously, it was necessary to understand the micro level (just as it was necessary to understand the chemicals that made up the aardvark) to have any chance of understand the macro, but that was not, in itself, enough.

The counterrevolutionaries, starting with Keynes’s old rival Friedrich Hayek at the LSE and the various luminaries who joined him in the Mont Pelerin Society, took aim directly at this notion that national economies are anything more than the sum of their parts. Politically, Skidelsky notes, this was due to a hostility to the very idea of statecraft (and, in a broader sense, of any collective good). National economies could indeed be reduced to the aggregate effect of millions of individual decisions, and, therefore, every element of macroeconomics had to be systematically “micro-founded.”

One reason this was such a radical position was that it was taken at exactly the same moment that microeconomics itself was completing a profound transformation—one that had begun with the marginal revolution of the late nineteenth century—from a technique for understanding how those operating on the market make decisions to a general philosophy of human life. It was able to do so, remarkably enough, by proposing a series of assumptions that even economists themselves were happy to admit were not really true: let us posit, they said, purely rational actors motivated exclusively by self-interest, who know exactly what they want and never change their minds, and have complete access to all relevant pricing information. This allowed them to make precise, predictive equations of exactly how individuals should be expected to act.
Surely there’s nothing wrong with creating simplified models. Arguably, this is how any science of human affairs has to proceed. But an empirical science then goes on to test those models against what people actually do, and adjust them accordingly. This is precisely what economists did not do. Instead, they discovered that, if one encased those models in mathematical formulae completely impenetrable to the noninitiate, it would be possible to create a universe in which those premises could never be refuted. (“All actors are engaged in the maximization of utility. What is utility? Whatever it is that an actor appears to be maximizing.”) The mathematical equations allowed economists to plausibly claim theirs was the only branch of social theory that had advanced to anything like a predictive science (even if most of their successful predictions were of the behavior of people who had themselves been trained in economic theory).

This allowed Homo economicus to invade the rest of the academy, so that by the 1950s and 1960s almost every scholarly discipline in the business of preparing young people for positions of power (political science, international relations, etc.) had adopted some variant of “rational choice theory” culled, ultimately, from microeconomics. By the 1980s and 1990s, it had reached a point where even the heads of art foundations or charitable organizations would not be considered fully qualified if they were not at least broadly familiar with a “science” of human affairs that started from the assumption that humans were fundamentally selfish and greedy.

These, then, were the “microfoundations” to which the neoclassical reformers demanded macroeconomics be returned. Here they were able to take advantage of certain undeniable weaknesses in Keynesian formulations, above all its inability to explain 1970s stagflation, to brush away the remaining Keynesian superstructure and return to the same hard-money, small-government policies that had been dominant in the nineteenth century. The familiar pattern ensued. Monetarism didn’t work; in the UK and then the US, such policies were quickly abandoned. But ideologically, the intervention was so effective that even when “new Keynesians” like Joseph Stiglitz or Paul Krugman returned to dominate the argument about macroeconomics, they still felt obliged to maintain the new microfoundations.

The problem, as Skidelsky emphasizes, is that if your initial assumptions are absurd, multiplying them a thousandfold will hardly make them less so. Or, as he puts it, rather less gently, “lunatic premises lead to mad conclusions”:
The efficient market hypothesis (EMH), made popular by Eugene Fama…is the application of rational expectations to financial markets. The rational expectations hypothesis (REH) says that agents optimally utilize all available information about the economy and policy instantly to adjust their expectations….
Thus, in the words of Fama,…“In an efficient market, competition among the many intelligent participants leads to a situation where…the actual price of a security will be a good estimate of its intrinsic value.” [Skidelsky’s italics]
In other words, we were obliged to pretend that markets could not, by definition, be wrong—if in the 1980s the land on which the Imperial compound in Tokyo was built, for example, was valued higher than that of all the land in New York City, then that would have to be because that was what it was actually worth. If there are deviations, they are purely random, “stochastic” and therefore unpredictable, temporary, and, ultimately, insignificant. In any case, rational actors will quickly step in to sweep up any undervalued stocks. Skidelsky drily remarks:
There is a paradox here. On the one hand, the theory says that there is no point in trying to profit from speculation, because shares are always correctly priced and their movements cannot be predicted. But on the other hand, if investors did not try to profit, the market would not be efficient because there would be no self-correcting mechanism….
Secondly, if shares are always correctly priced, bubbles and crises cannot be generated by the market….
This attitude leached into policy: “government officials, starting with [Federal Reserve Chairman] Alan Greenspan, were unwilling to burst the bubble precisely because they were unwilling to even judge that it was a bubble.” The EMH made the identification of bubbles impossible because it ruled them out a priori.
If there is an answer to the queen’s famous question of why no one saw the crash coming, this would be it.
At this point, we have come full circle. After such a catastrophic embarrassment, orthodox economists fell back on their strong suit—academic politics and institutional power. In the UK, one of the first moves of the new Conservative-Liberal Democratic Coalition in 2010 was to reform the higher education system by tripling tuition and instituting an American-style regime of student loans. Common sense might have suggested that if the education system was performing successfully (for all its foibles, the British university system was considered one of the best in the world), while the financial system was operating so badly that it had nearly destroyed the global economy, the sensible thing might be to reform the financial system to be a bit more like the educational system, rather than the other way around. An aggressive effort to do the opposite could only be an ideological move. It was a full-on assault on the very idea that knowledge could be anything other than an economic good.

Similar moves were made to solidify control over the institutional structure. The BBC, a once proudly independent body, under the Tories has increasingly come to resemble a state broadcasting network, their political commentators often reciting almost verbatim the latest talking points of the ruling party—which, at least economically, were premised on the very theories that had just been discredited. Political debate simply assumed that the usual “harsh medicine” and Gladstonian “fiscal probity” were the only solution; at the same time, the Bank of England began printing money like mad and, effectively, handing it out to the one percent in an unsuccessful attempt to kick-start inflation. The practical results were, to put it mildly, uninspiring. Even at the height of the eventual recovery, in the fifth-richest country in the world, something like one British citizen in twelve experienced hunger, up to and including going entire days without food. If an “economy” is to be defined as the means by which a human population provides itself with its material needs, the British economy is increasingly dysfunctional. Frenetic efforts on the part of the British political class to change the subject (Brexit) can hardly go on forever. Eventually, real issues will have to be addressed.

Economic theory as it exists increasingly resembles a shed full of broken tools. This is not to say there are no useful insights here, but fundamentally the existing discipline is designed to solve another century’s problems. The problem of how to determine the optimal distribution of work and resources to create high levels of economic growth is simply not the same problem we are now facing: i.e., how to deal with increasing technological productivity, decreasing real demand for labor, and the effective management of care work, without also destroying the Earth. This demands a different science. The “microfoundations” of current economics are precisely what is standing in the way of this. Any new, viable science will either have to draw on the accumulated knowledge of feminism, behavioral economics, psychology, and even anthropology to come up with theories based on how people actually behave, or once again embrace the notion of emergent levels of complexity—or, most likely, both.

Intellectually, this won’t be easy. Politically, it will be even more difficult. Breaking through neoclassical economics’ lock on major institutions, and its near-theological hold over the media—not to mention all the subtle ways it has come to define our conceptions of human motivations and the horizons of human possibility—is a daunting prospect. Presumably, some kind of shock would be required. What might it take? Another 2008-style collapse? Some radical political shift in a major world government? A global youth rebellion? However it will come about, books like this—and quite possibly this book—will play a crucial part.

Post in evidenza

The Great Taking - The Movie

David Webb exposes the system Central Bankers have in place to take everything from everyone Webb takes us on a 50-year journey of how the C...