The ECB’s Illusory Independence
https://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/europe-least-independent-central-bank-by-yanis-varoufakis-2016-06
ATHENS
– A commitment to the independence of central banks is a vital part of
the creed that “serious” policymakers are expected to uphold
(privatization, labor-market “flexibility,” and so on). But what are
central banks meant to be independent of? The answer seems obvious:
governments.
In this sense, the European Central Bank is the
quintessentially independent central bank: No single government stands
behind it, and it is expressly prohibited from standing behind any of
the national governments whose central bank it is. And yet the ECB is
the least independent central bank in the developed world.
The
key difficulty is the ECB’s “no bailout” clause – the ban on aiding an
insolvent member-state government. Because commercial banks are an
essential source of funding for member governments, the ECB is forced to
refuse liquidity to banks domiciled in insolvent members. Thus, the ECB
is founded on rules that prevent it from serving as lender of last
resort.
The
Achilles heel of this arrangement is the lack of insolvency procedures
for euro members. When, for example, Greece became insolvent in 2010,
the German and French governments denied its government the right to
default on debt held by German and French banks. Greece’s first
“bailout” was used to make French and German banks whole. But doing so
deepened Greece’s insolvency.
It
was at this point that the ECB’s lack of independence was fully
exposed. Since 2010, the Greek government has been relying on a sequence
of loans that it can never repay to maintain a façade of solvency. A
truly independent ECB, adhering to its own rules, should have refused to
accept as collateral all debt liabilities guaranteed by the Greek state
– government bonds, treasury bills, and the more than €50 billion ($56
billion) of IOUs that Greece’s banks have issued to remain afloat.
Of
course, such a refusal would close down Greek banks and lead
immediately to Greece’s exit from the eurozone, because the government
would be forced to issue its own liquidity. The only alternative would
be a meaningful debt restructuring to end Greece’s insolvency. Alas,
Europe’s political establishment, unwilling to adopt either option, has
chosen to extend Greece’s insolvency – which it pretends has been
resolved through new loan tranches.
The
ECB’s ongoing acquiescence in the extend-and-pretend charade demanded
by Greece’s creditors has demolished its claim to be independent. To
keep Greece’s banks open, and accept their government-guaranteed
collateral, the ECB is obliged to grant Greek debt an exemption from its
no-insolvency rule. And, to keep the noose firmly around Greece’s neck,
Germany insists that this exemption is conditional on its approval –
or, in euro-speak, that the Eurogroup of eurozone finance ministers
confirms that “Greece’s fiscal consolidation and reform program are on
track.”
So,
in effect, it is politicians that tell the ECB when to cut off
liquidity to an entire banking system. While the ECB can claim
independence vis-à-vis insolvent, peripheral governments, it is entirely
at the mercy of the governments of Europe’s creditor countries.
To
illustrate the ECB’s conundrum, it is worthwhile revisiting the
creditors’ treatment of the Greek government elected in January 2015. By
December 2014, it had become clear that the previous government was on
its last legs and that the leftist Syriza party was on its way to power.
The governor of Greece’s central bank, an arm of the ECB, “predicted”
that markets were facing a liquidity squeeze,
implying that a Syriza victory would render the banking system unsafe –
a statement that would be inane were it not calculated to start a bank
run.
By
the time I became Finance Minister that February, after Syriza’s
electoral victory, the bank run was in full swing and stocks were in
free fall. The reason, of course, was the common knowledge that Germany,
vehemently opposed to our government, was about to switch off the green
light required by the ECB to maintain the exemptions allowing it to
accept Greek collateral.
To
stabilize the situation, I flew to London to address financiers with a
message of moderation and sensible policies regarding both reforms and
debt restructuring. The following morning, the stock exchange rebounded 13%, bank shares rose by more than 20%, and the bank run ceased.
On that day, the ECB, pressured by Germany, rescinded an important part of its exemption,
thereby cutting off Greek banks’ direct access to the ECB and diverting
them to pricier financing from Greece’s central bank (so-called
emergency liquidity assistance). Unsurprisingly, stock prices plummeted
and the bank run returned with a vengeance, bleeding €45 billion of
deposits out of the system over the next few months. Meanwhile, Germany
and other creditors began to push Greece to accept new austerity
measures as the price of reversing the “ECB’s” decision.
This
was not the ECB’s only politically driven intervention. Equally
aggressive was its decision to curtail Greek banks’ spending on
government treasuries, by instructing them to refuse debt rollovers.
This diminished my ministry’s capacity to repay the International
Monetary Fund, which was insisting on drastic pension cuts and on the
removal of the last protections for Greek workers.
For
five months, as the ECB’s noose tightened, we resisted German and IMF
demands for further austerity. Finally, the complete cessation of all
liquidity to Greece’s banks in June 2015 forced their closure. This was
followed by the final push to divide our government and force the prime
minister to capitulate – as he did, accepting the latest
extend-and-pretend loan of €85 billion.
Almost
a year later, Greece’s creditors were pushing for even greater
austerity in exchange for more loan tranches. At this point, Greece’s
central-bank governor (who had triggered the original bank run in
December 2014) publicly alleged
that our government’s stance until June 2015 caused the loss of €45
billion worth of deposits, the ensuing bank closures, and the new
extend-and-pretend loans. The bully was blaming the victim, and the ECB
was openly embracing its role as enforcer for its political masters: the
creditors.
The
eurozone’s current design makes ECB independence impossible. Worse, the
pretense of independence serves as a fig leaf for interventions that
are not only politically driven, but that are also utterly inconsistent
with the principles of liberal democracy.
Nessun commento:
Posta un commento