Tilting At Windmills: The Faustian Folly Of Quantitative Easing
http://www.forbes.com/sites/stevekeen/2016/02/16/tilting-at-windmills-the-faustian-folly-of-quantitative-easing/#2ab572c8358c
Opinions expressed by Forbes Contributors are their own.
As I explained in my last post,
banks can’t “lend out reserves” under any circumstances, which
undermines a major rationale that Central Bank economists gave for
undertaking Quantitative Easing in the first place. Consequently, the
hope that Bernanke expressed in 2009 is “To Dream The Impossible Dream”:
But without the poetry:
But rather than rescuing Central Bankers from folly, this escape clause is an unwitting pact with the devil: they are now caught in a Faustian bargain. Any attempt to terminate QE is likely to end in deflating the asset markets that it inflated in the first place, which will cause the Central Banks to once more come “riding to the rescue” on their monetary Rocinante.
While Central Bankers can personally still join Faust and ascend to Heaven—thanks to their comfortable public salaries and pensions—the rest of us have been thrust into the Hell of expanding and bursting speculative bubbles, hoist on the ill-designed lance of QE. Bernanke is a rich man’s incompetent Frank N. Furter: confronting a wet and shivering couple, he promises to remove the cause—but not the symptom:
To dream the impossible dream
To fight the unbeatable foe
To bear with unbearable sorrow
To run where the brave dare not go
But without the poetry:
Large increases in bank reserves brought about through central bank loans or purchases of securities are a characteristic feature of the unconventional policy approach known as quantitative easing. The idea behind quantitative easing is to provide banks with substantial excess liquidity in the hope that they will choose to use some part of that liquidity to make loans or buy other assets. (Bernanke 2009, “The Federal Reserve’s Balance Sheet: An Update”What a folly this was—almost. The one out that Bernanke gives himself from pure delusional babble is the phrase “or buy other assets”—because that’s the one thing that banks can actually do with the excess reserves that QE has generated.
But rather than rescuing Central Bankers from folly, this escape clause is an unwitting pact with the devil: they are now caught in a Faustian bargain. Any attempt to terminate QE is likely to end in deflating the asset markets that it inflated in the first place, which will cause the Central Banks to once more come “riding to the rescue” on their monetary Rocinante.
While Central Bankers can personally still join Faust and ascend to Heaven—thanks to their comfortable public salaries and pensions—the rest of us have been thrust into the Hell of expanding and bursting speculative bubbles, hoist on the ill-designed lance of QE. Bernanke is a rich man’s incompetent Frank N. Furter: confronting a wet and shivering couple, he promises to remove the cause—but not the symptom:
Recommended by Forbes
So, come up to the lab,/ and see what’s on the slab!/ I see you shiver with antici… …pation./ But maybe the rain/ isn’t really to blame,/ so I’ll remove the cause…/ [chuckles] but not the symptom. (“Sweet Transvestite”)Bernanke’s QE instead maintains the symptoms of the crisis, but does nothing about its cause. It generates rampant inequality, drives asset prices sky-high and causes frequent financial panics—while doing nothing to reduce the far too high a level of private debt that caused the crisis.
Let’s put QE on the slab in my lab—my Minsky software—and track the logic of the monetary flows that QE can trigger. Figure 1 shows the full model; the Tables in this post go through it step by step.
Figure 1: The full Minsky model of QE (with no simulation settings as yet)
[Here’s a quick primer on Minsky’s accounting conventions for those who haven’t read the previous post. Minsky shows Assets as positive sums, and Liabilities and Equity as negative, so that any operation on a row sums to zero: therefore, positive entries increase Assets, and reduce Liabilities and Equity; while negative entries reduce Assets, and increase Liabilities and Assets. This might look strange on first glance, but it (a) enforces the “Fundamental Law of Accounting” that “Assets minus Liabilities equal Equity”, since when a transaction is properly recorded, each row sums to zero; and (b) since Minsky maintains interlocking “Godley Tables”—named in honour of Wynne Godley—it shows a Liability from one sector’s point of view as an Asset from another’s. The program can thus accurately track how money flows through the financial system.]I make some genuine simplifying assumptions to make the Godley Tables simpler to read (genuine in the sense that my results don’t depend on the assumptions—unlike so-called “simplifying assumptions” in much of Mainstream economics). I treat QE as a loan (rather than a bond purchase), and I ignore all other transactions in the economy apart from those related to QE.
The first step in the model is the Central Bank loan of QE to Private Bank 1 (PB1). That increases the Assets and Liabilities of the Central Bank: LoansPB rise by QE, as do ReservesB!. Since Central Banks now pay interest on excess reserves, I include the flow of interest payments IntER as well. This is financed from the essentially limitless equity of the Central Bank, and—from its point of view—adds to the Reserves of Private Bank 1 (if the rate is positive). These operations are shown in Table 1:
Table 1: QE and interest payments on Reserves from the Central Bank’s perspective
Central Bank | Asset | Liability | Equity | Row Sum | |
Flows ↓/Accounts→ | LoansPB | ReservesB1 | ReservesB2 | EquityCB | |
QE loan | QE | -QE | 0 | ||
Interest on Reserves | -IntER | IntER | 0 |
These same operations are recorded on Private Bank 1’s accounts as shown in Table 2. This confirms one of Joe Stiglitz’s points about QE from his article that I otherwise criticized in my last post: Banks have indeed been earning “earning nearly $30 billion – completely risk-free – during the last five years” thanks to QE.
Table 2: QE and interest payments on Reserves from the recipient Private Bank PB1’s perspective
PB1 | Assets | Liability | Equity | Row Sum | |||
Flows ↓/Accounts→ | Shares | ReservesB1 | LoansCB | Poor | Rich | EquityB1 | |
QE loan | QE | -QE | 0 | ||||
Interest on Reserves | IntER | -IntER | 0 |
Now what happens to the QE funds once they’re in Private Bank 1 (PB1 for short)? It can’t simply lend them out, as I showed in my last post—the belief that they can violates the Fundamental Law of Accounting. But PB1 can buy assets with it, which I’ll show here as a purchase of shares from a broker who banks with another Private Bank PB2. This does of course decrease PB1’s reserves—mission half-accomplished.
Table 3: Buying shares from PB1‘s perspective
PB1 | Assets | Liability | Equity | Row Sum | |||
Flows ↓/Accounts→ | Shares | ReservesB1 | LoansCB | Poor | Rich | EqB1 | |
Buy shares from broker | SharesQE | - SharesQE | 0 |
The Super-Rich spend of course, but more slowly than anyone else relative to their wealth, simply because they have so much more of it than anyone else. And they spend a lot of that on each other—buying and selling assets and luxury possessions. Given the slower speed at which they spend, the money created by QE dwells here the longest—and therefore their wealth grows more than that of any other social group thanks to QE.
Table 4: PB1‘s purchase of shares from PB2‘s perspective
PB2 | Assets | Liability | Equity | Row Sum | |
Flows ↓/Accounts→ | ReservesB2 | Broker | SuperRich | EquityB2 | |
Sell shares to PB1 | SharesQE | - SharesQE | 0 | ||
Buy shares from Super-rich | SharesQE2 | -SharesQE2 | |||
Pay Dividends | -Dividends | Dividends | 0 | ||
Pay bonuses to staff | -Bonus | Bonus | 0 |
Table 5: Payment of dividends and bonuses from PB1‘s perspective
PB1 | Assets | Liability | Equity | Row Sum | ||||
Flows ↓/Accounts→ | Shares | ReservesB1 | LoansCB | Poor | Rich | EquityB1 | ||
Pay Dividends | Dividends | -Dividends | 0 | |||||
Pay bonuses to staff | Bonus | -Bonus | 0 | |||||
Buy goods from dealer | -Dealer | Dealer |
Oh Dear! The reserves that PB2 got rid of by paying dividends and bonuses out have ended back at PB1. There has therefore been no net change in the aggregate level of reserves. But, finally, there is an operation that puts money into the hands of poorer households: the Rich households use part of their Bonus to buy something from the Poor households (far be it from me to insinuate that this might sometimes be something illicit!).
Now let’s take stock—to coin a phrase. All these operations have done nothing to reduce the aggregate level of Reserves: they’ve simply shuffled them from one bank to another. In fact, even if QE stops, reserves grow at the rate of interest on reserves.
Banks come out of this as rather innocent: they can’t do what Ben Bernanke (and now Joe Stiglitz) are berating them for: not only can’t they lend out Excess Reserves, they can’t get rid of them either. It’s not their fault that the only way they can individually attempt to do so amounts to playing “hot potato”— trying to reduce their reserves while simultaneously boosting another bank’s reserves—by buying assets, since this is what Don Quixote (sorry, Bernanke) intended them to do in the first place. However, these misunderstood institutions are nonetheless “crying all the way to the bank” with the risk-free earnings that QE has given them.
The only ways that Reserves can fall are (a) if the Central Bank takes them back or (b) if some part of the public withdraws its money from deposit accounts as cash. Under the dynamics of QE itself, Reserves can only rise (so long as the interest on Excess Reserves is positive—which may be one unstated reason why Central Banks are implementing negative rates now, if anyone inside one of them has worked this out).
The real economy has thus received some impetus from QE, but only a relatively trivial amount of the money created has got into circulation in Main Street. As Michael Hudson puts it, Bernanke’s helicopter dumped money on Wall Street, not Main Street.
The bubble before the financial crisis had already exaggerated income inequality past what is sustainable in a capitalist society. Central Bank meddling via QE has made this problem worse, and without the illusion of a boom (like the Internet and Subprime Bubbles) to make it seem somehow palatable.
It has done this, not only by giving money to the Super-Rich, but by inflating asset prices, driving them well above the increase in consumer prices and wages. This is yet another symptom of the bubbles before the crisis, when speculative lending by banks drove asset prices (shares in the DotCom Bubble, house prices in the SubPrime Bubble) into the stratosphere in the first place. The S&P 500 fell from 45 at the peak of the DotCom Bubble to around 25 when the SubPrime Crisis began, and 15 in the depth of the crisis—see Figure 2. QE drove it back up to 25.
Now Stockmarkets worldwide are falling again, partly in response to
the The Fed’s tentative and foolish attempts to unwind its original bold
and foolish intervention into inflating asset prices. But it will be
dragged back in again if it attempts to unwind QE, because all the dynamics explained in the preceding Tables works in reverse as well.
So long as it continues to believe that sky-high asset prices are
actually good for the economy, it can’t afford not to continue meddling
in them.
Figure 2: Robert Shiller’s Cyclically Adjusted PE Ratio
Figure 3: Shiller’s long term real house price index
Figure 2: Robert Shiller’s Cyclically Adjusted PE Ratio
Figure 3: Shiller’s long term real house price index
All the while, the Fed has not only ignored the real cause of both the Asset Price Bubbles and the crisis itself—the private debt bubble that financed the DotCom and SubPrime Bubbles—its Impossible Dream was that QE would cause this debt bubble to rise again too. Quoting Bernanke from 2009 again, “The idea behind quantitative easing is to provide banks with substantial excess liquidity in the hope that they will choose to use some part of that liquidity to make loans”.
Bernanke and his Central Bank colleagues around the world have made the symptoms of the crisis worse, in the hope that the cause would get worse, thus curing the patient.
Take a good look at Figure 4. Anyone who thinks than more private debt in America is a good thing is as delusional as Don Quixote.
Figure 4: Estimated long term US private debt to GDP ratio using Fed data since 1945 and Census data since 1834
The Man of La Mancha’s magnificent song “The Impossible Dream” ends with this stirring paean to chivalry:
And the world will be better for thisCentral Bankers, the Don Quixote’s of our modern age, are making the world a far worse place than it would be without their foolish gallantry.
That one man, scorned and covered with scars,
Still strove with his last ounce of courage
To reach the unreachable star.
Technical Appendix
Here’s a screenshot of a “quick and dirty” simulation using this model, including the ability to turn off or reverse QE. It would be fun to add an asset price component here (assume fixed supply and the flow of new money from QE driving price change) and see what happens.
If you’d like to check this out, here are the links: Minsky model before simulation added (Model; LaTeX code; Matlab code); model after simulation added (Model; LaTeX code; Matlab code). To run Minsky, download it from here. The current Windows-only beta build overcomes speed issues with Godley Tables in the current release version (but it might introduce some other bugs)
The equations for the model (generated by Minsky as LaTeX output from the file menu) are:
Nessun commento:
Posta un commento