Posted on November 20, 2015 by Ellen Brown
In uncertain times, “cash is king,” but central bankers are
systematically moving to eliminate that option. Is it really about
stimulating the economy? Or is there some deeper, darker threat afoot?
Remember those old ads showing a senior couple lounging on a warm beach, captioned “Let your money work for you”? Or
the scene in Mary Poppins
where young Michael is being advised to put his tuppence in the bank,
so that it can compound into “all manner of private enterprise,”
including “bonds, chattels, dividends, shares, shipyards, amalgamations .
. . .”?
That may still work if you’re a Wall Street banker, but if you’re an
ordinary saver with your money in the bank, you may soon be paying the
bank to hold your funds rather than the reverse.
Four European central banks – the European Central Bank, the Swiss
National Bank, Sweden’s Riksbank, and Denmark’s Nationalbank –
have now imposed negative interest rates
on the reserves they hold for commercial banks; and discussion has
turned to whether it’s time to pass those costs on to consumers. The
Bank of Japan and the Federal Reserve are still at ZIRP (Zero Interest
Rate Policy), but
several Fed officials have also begun calling for NIRP (negative rates).
The stated justification for this move is to stimulate “demand” by
forcing consumers to withdraw their money and go shopping with it. When
an economy is struggling,
it is standard practice
for a central bank to cut interest rates, making saving less
attractive. This is supposed to boost spending and kick-start an
economic recovery.
That is the theory, but central banks have already pushed the prime
rate to zero, and still their economies are languishing. To the
uninitiated observer, that means the theory is wrong and needs to be
scrapped. But not to our intrepid central bankers, who are now
experimenting with pushing rates
below zero.
Locking the Door to Bank Runs: The Cashless Society
The problem with imposing negative interest on savers, as
explained in the UK Telegraph,
is that “there’s a limit, what economists called the ‘zero lower
bound’. Cut rates too deeply, and savers would end up facing negative
returns. In that case, this could encourage people to take their savings
out of the bank and hoard them in cash. This could slow, rather than
boost, the economy.”
Again, to the ordinary observer, this would seem to signal that
negative interest rates won’t work and the approach needs to be
abandoned. But not to our undaunted central bankers, who have chosen
instead to plug this hole in their leaky theory by moving to
eliminate cash as an option.
If your only choice is to keep your money in a digital account in a
bank and spend it with a bank card or credit card or checks, negative
interest can be imposed with impunity. This is already happening in
Sweden, and other countries are close behind.
As reported on Wolfstreet.com:
The War on Cash is advancing on all fronts. One region
that has hogged the headlines with its war against physical currency is
Scandinavia. Sweden became the first country to enlist its own citizens
as largely willing guinea pigs in a dystopian economic experiment:
negative interest rates in a cashless society. As Credit Suisse reports,
no matter where you go or what you want to purchase, you will find a
small ubiquitous sign saying “Vi hanterar ej kontanter” (“We don’t
accept cash”) . . . .
The Lesson of Gesell’s Decaying Currency
Whether negative interests will actually stimulate an economic recovery, however, remains in doubt.
Proponents of the theory cite Silvio Gesell and the Wörgl experiment of the 1930s. As explained by Charles Eisenstein in
Sacred Economics:
The pioneering theoretician of negative-interest money
was the German-Argentinean businessman Silvio Gesell, who called it
“free-money” (Freigeld) . . . . The system he proposed in his 1906
masterwork, The Natural Economic Order, was to use paper currency to
which a stamp costing a small fraction of the note’s value had to be
affixed periodically. This effectively attached a maintenance cost to
monetary wealth.
. . . [In 1932], the depressed town of Wörgl, Austria, issued its own
stamp scrip inspired by Gesell . . . . The Wörgl currency was by all
accounts a huge success. Roads were paved, bridges built, and back taxes
were paid. The unemployment rate plummeted and the economy thrived,
attracting the attention of nearby towns. Mayors and officials from all
over the world began to visit Wörgl until, as in Germany, the central
government abolished the Wörgl currency and the town slipped back into
depression.
. . . [T]he Wörgl currency bore a demurrage rate [a maintenance
charge for carrying money] of 1 percent per month. Contemporary accounts
attributed to this the very rapid velocity of the currencies’
circulation. Instead of generating interest and growing, accumulation of
wealth became a burden, much like possessions are a burden to the
nomadic hunter-gatherer. As theorized by Gesell, money afflicted with
loss-inducing properties ceased to be preferred over any other commodity
as a store of value.
There is a critical difference, however, between the Wörgl currency
and the modern-day central bankers’ negative interest scheme. The Wörgl
government first
issued its new “free money,” getting it into
the local economy and increasing purchasing power, before taxing a
portion of it back. And the proceeds of the stamp tax went to the city,
to be used for the benefit of the taxpayers. As Eisenstein observes:
It is impossible to prove . . . that the rejuvenating
effects of these currencies came from demurrage and not from the
increase in the money supply . . . .
Today’s central bankers are proposing to tax
existing money,
diminishing spending power without first building it up. And the interest will go to private bankers, not to the local government.
Consumers today already have very little discretionary money.
Imposing negative interest without first adding new money into the
economy means they will have even
less money to spend. This would be more likely to prompt them to save their scarce funds than to go on a shopping spree.
People are not keeping their money in the bank today for the interest
(which is already nearly non-existent). It is for the convenience of
writing checks, issuing bank cards, and storing their money in a “safe”
place. They would no doubt be willing to pay a modest negative interest
for that convenience; but if the fee got too high, they might pull their
money out and save it elsewhere. The fee itself, however, would not
drive them to buy things they did not otherwise need.
Is There a Bigger Threat than a Sluggish Economy?
The scheme to impose negative interest and eliminate cash seems so
unlikely to stimulate the economy that one wonders if that is the real
motive. Stopping tax evaders and terrorists (real or presumed) are other
proposed justifications for going cashless. Economist
Martin Armstrong goes further
and suggests that the goal is to gain totalitarian control over our
money. In a cashless society, our savings can be taxed away by the
banks; the threat of bank runs by worried savers can be eliminated; and
the too-big-to-fail banks can be assured that ample deposits will be
there when they need to confiscate them through bail-ins to stay afloat.
And that may be the real threat on the horizon: a major derivatives
default that hits the largest banks, those that do the vast majority of
derivatives trading. On November 10, 2015, the Wall Street Journal
reported the results of a study requested by Senator Elizabeth Warren
and Rep. Elijah Cummings, involving the cost to taxpayers of the
rollback of the Dodd-Frank Act in the “cromnibus” spending bill last
December.
As Jessica Desvarieux put it
on the Real News Network, “the rule reversal allows banks to keep $10
trillion in swaps trades on their books, which taxpayers could be on the
hook for if the banks need another bailout.”
The promise of Dodd-Frank, however, was that there would be “no more
taxpayer bailouts.” Instead, insolvent systemically-risky banks were
supposed to “bail in” (confiscate) the money of their creditors,
including their depositors (the largest class of creditor of any bank).
That could explain the push to go cashless. By quietly eliminating the
possibility of cash withdrawals, the central bank can make sure the
deposits are there to be grabbed when disaster strikes.
If central bankers are seriously trying to stimulate the economy with
negative interest rates, they need to repeat the Wörgl experiment in
full. They need to first get some new money into the economy, money that
goes directly to the consumers and local businessmen who will spend it.
This could be achieved in a number of ways: with a national dividend;
or by using quantitative easing for infrastructure or low-interest loans
to states; or by funding free tuition for higher education. Consumers
will hit the malls when they have some new discretionary income to
spend.
_____________
Ellen Brown is an attorney, founder of the
Public Banking Institute, and author of twelve books including the best-selling
Web of Debt. Her latest book,
The Public Bank Solution, explores successful public banking models historically and globally. Her 300+ blog articles are at
EllenBrown.com. Listen to “
It’s Our Money with Ellen Brown” on PRN.FM.