Home » Blog » 2015 » August » 22 » Sovereign Money –…
There are a number of common objections and concerns with the proposal to switch to a
sovereign money system. Here we deal with the 3 areas of objections:
-
“It won’t work”
-
“It’s unnecessary”
-
“Even if it works it will be damaging”
1. “IT WON’T WORK”
A very common criticism or misunderstanding of Sovereign Money
proposals is that they seek to prevent banks from acting as credit
intermediaries. As explained in Jackson & Dyson (2013),
banks would lend in a sovereign money system, but they would do so by
borrowing pre-existing sovereign money (originally created by the
central bank) from savers and then lending those funds to borrowers.
This would be different from the current system, where banks simply
credit the borrower’s account and create new money in the process. In
other words,
credit intermediation between borrowers and savers would be the very function of the lending side of a bank in the sovereign money system.
https://www.positivemoney.org/2012/03/myths-money-banking/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/05/full-reserve-banking-really-hard-understand-reply-john-aziz/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/04/ann-pettifor-there-will-be-no-shortage-of-money/
“THERE WOULD BE LITTLE SCOPE FOR MATURITY TRANSFORMATION”
Definitions of maturity transformation tend to focus on the banking
sector’s role in utilising short-term sources of funding to finance
long-term lending. This
maturity transformation will still take place
in a sovereign money system. Sovereign Money proposals have bank
liabilities – Investment Accounts – set at a range of maturities, from a
minimum of 4 weeks (although the regulator could set a higher minimum)
to a number of months or years. So banks’ loans could have maturities
ranging from a few months, to a number of years. In the extreme,
mortgage loans would have maturities of 25 years or more, although in
practice many mortgages are refinanced earlier and the average maturity
of mortgage loans is as little as 7 years. Such a business plan would
see new investments and repayments on existing loans being used to fund
new loans and Investment Account withdrawals.
It is important to remember that
loan repayments in a Sovereign Money system would not result in the destruction of money.
In the current monetary system, the deposits used to repay bank loans
disappear or are ‘destroyed’ as a result of the accounting process used
to repay a loan. In contrast, in a Sovereign Money system debt
repayments would not result in money being destroyed. Instead, loan
repayments would be made by debtors transferring Sovereign Money from
their Transaction Accounts to the Investment Pool account of their bank.
The bank would now have re-acquired the Sovereign Money that it
originally lent on behalf of its investors. Therefore investors looking
to deposit savings on a short-term basis, which may have been used to
make a long-term loan, would receive their return from the repayments of
the borrower.
More generally, maturity transformation can be undertaken by
organisations other than banks. The peer-to-peer lending market is also
developing a range of loan intermediation models involving internal
intra-lender markets for loan participations, which could be adopted by
banks to further enhance the flexibility of sovereign money financing.
The securities markets also do maturity transformation every day.
Companies issue long-term liabilities which are bought by investors, and
stock and bond markets enable investors to liquidate their investments
instantly by selling them to others. Banks are perhaps historically
regarded as providing an essential service to borrowers whose
liabilities are not marketable (i.e. they cannot be traded in financial
markets), but virtually all liabilities can now be converted into
marketable securities through the intermediation of banks, and that is
not something that the sovereign money proposals will change.
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/04/ann-pettifor-there-will-be-no-shortage-of-money/
“IT WOULD NOT BE FEASIBLE FOR THE STATE TO ESTABLISH CONTROL OF THE MONEY SUPPLY”
In 1979, attempts were made principally by the US and UK authorities,
to manage the economy by controlling the amount of money created by the
central bank. This was a failure, because it was based on the
neo-classical fallacy that central banks determine the quantity of
central bank reserves and the banking sector multiply that amount into a
larger amount of broad money (bank deposits), to a multiple determined
by the reserve ratio.
Yet, as Keynes had recognised almost fifty years earlier, banks were
able to create as much broad money as they pleased so long as they did
so in step. This is because reserves are primarily used for payment
settlement purposes amongst banks themselves. Only banks and building
societies have access to Central Bank accounts, meaning reserves cannot
leave the system. If banks create large amounts of broad money in step,
then the payments between them will cancel out, the net settlements
between them will remain the same, and no additional reserves will need
to be injected into the system. In this system, it is a mathematical
certainty that if one bank is experiencing a shortage of reserves,
another bank will have a surplus. As long as the banks with the surplus
are willing to lending to those experiencing a shortage, new broad money
can be continuously created. Central banks (as part of the state) can’t
establish control of the money supply (through restricting the supply
of reserves) when it is commercial banks that create broad money through
lending.
The sovereign money proposals address this problem by preventing
banks from creating demand deposits, liabilities, which function as the
means of payment in the modern economy. Instead,
money, in the
sense of the means of payment, would exist as liabilities of the central
bank, and could therefore be created (or destroyed) only by the central
bank. This would prevent loss of control of the money stock
and provide the central bank with absolute and direct control of the
aggregate of these balances.
https://www.positivemoney.org/2011/08/steve-horwitzs-pro-fractional-reserve-arguments/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2013/02/detlev-schlichter-on-positive-money-a-response/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2012/11/criticisms-of-positive-money-by-mike-robinson-of-uk-column/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2012/07/eleven-arguments-against-interest-rate-adjustments/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2012/03/myths-money-banking/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/06/disagree-ann-pettifor/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/05/power-create-money-safer-state-banks/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/04/ann-pettifor-there-will-be-no-shortage-of-money/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/02/drews-article-objections-edit/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2013/07/will-there-be-enough-credit-in-the-positive-money-system/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2013/05/would-positive-money-system-be-inflationary/
“A COMMITTEE CANNOT ACCURATELY DECIDE HOW MUCH MONEY SHOULD BE CREATED.”
This argument runs as follows:
“A centralised committee can’t possibly make a decision as complex as how much money is needed in the economy as a whole.”
This is a problem that applies to any monetary policy regime in which
there is a central bank, including the existing one in which the central
bank sets the base rate of interest. It is therefore
not an argument against a Sovereign Money system per se, but an argument against the existence of central banks.
In practice, the Monetary Policy Committee’s
decision-making process on the rate of growth of money creation
would work in the same way that decisions on interest rate policy
are currently made.
If, in the current system, the MPC would vote to lower interest rates,
then in a sovereign money system they would vote to increase the rate at
which money is created. The opposite also applies: if they would vote
to raise interest rates (to discourage borrowing and therefore reduce
money creation by banks), then in a sovereign money system they would
vote to slow the rate at which money is created. As with the decision to
alter interest rates, the Committee would need to respond to feedback
from the economy and adjust their decisions on monthly basis. But
whereas the setting of interest rates affects the economy through a long
and uncertain transmission mechanism, money creation directed through
government spending leads directly to a boost in GDP and (potentially)
employment. The feedback is likely to happen much faster and therefore
be easier to respond to.
Secondly, the argument is also based on the assumption that banks, by
assessing loan applications on a one-by-one basis, will result in an
overall level of money creation that is appropriate for the economy.
Yet, during the run up to the financial crisis, when excessive lending
for mortgages pushed up house prices and banks assumed that house prices
would continue to rise at over 10% a year, almost every individual
mortgage application looked like a ‘good bet’ that should be approved.
From the bank’s perspective, even if a borrower could not repay the
loan, rising house prices meant that a bank would cover its costs even
if it had to repossess the house. In other words, even if the loan would
not be repaid and the house repossessed, the bank would most likely not
suffer a loss, as the repossessed house was consistently increasing in
value. So it is quite possible for decisions taken by thousands of
individual loan officers to amount to an outcome that is damaging for
society.
More importantly is the system dynamics of such an arrangement. When
banks create additional money by lending, it can create the appearance
of an economic boom (as happened before the crisis). This makes banks
and potential borrowers more confident, and leads to greater lending/
borrowing, in a pro-cyclical fashion. Without anybody playing the role
of ‘thermostat’ in this system, money creation will continue to
accelerate until something breaks down.
In contrast, in a sovereign money system, there is a
clear thermostat
to balance the economy. In times when the economy is in recession or
growth is slow, the MCC will be able to increase the rate of money
creation to boost aggregate demand. If growth is very high and
inflationary pressures are increasing, they can slow down the rate of
money creation. At no point will they be able to get the perfect rate of
money creation, but it would be extremely difficult for them to get it
as wrong as the banks are destined to.
It is also important to clarify that in a Sovereign Money system,
it is still banks – and not the central bank – that make decisions about who they will lend to
and on what basis. The only decision taken by the central bank is
concerning the creation of new money; whereas, all lending decisions
will be taken by banks and other forms of finance companies.
https://www.positivemoney.org/2012/10/full-reserve-banking-does-not-mean-a-bank-bailout/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2012/07/eleven-arguments-against-interest-rate-adjustments/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/11/sovereign-money-response-andrea-leadsom-economic-secretary-treasury/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/06/disagree-ann-pettifor/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/05/power-create-money-safer-state-banks/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/04/ann-pettifor-there-will-be-no-shortage-of-money/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2013/05/would-positive-money-system-be-inflationary/
In a Sovereign Money system the Monetary Policy Committee does not
attempt to moderate inflation by adjusting interest rates. Instead, it
adjusts the rate of money creation directly,
by instructing the central bank to create money at a certain percentage
growth rate. Any newly created money is transferred to government, and
is then spent directly into the real economy, either through government
spending or through direct transfers to citizens, or tax cuts. There is a
much more direct and certain transmission mechanism between changes in
monetary policy (i.e. the rate of money creation) and the impact on the
real economy.
For this reason, we cannot see any reason why it would be harder to
judge a central bank that controls money creation directly than one that
relies on indirect and uncertain means of influencing the economy, in
the form of short-term interest rates.
“IT’S IMPOSSIBLE FOR BANKS TO BE PROFITABLE IN THIS MODEL.” / “BANKING WOULD BE UNVIABLE.”
In a sovereign money system banks provide two essential functions, both of which can be highly profitable:
1) The payments system. Billions of pounds are transferred between accounts every single day.
MasterCard, Visa and various other payment networks all run successful businesses
by providing payment systems. It is unrealistic to think that banks
would be unable to find a way to generate a profit given the fact that
they sit at the centre of the national payments system.
2) The lending/saving function. Banks would perform this function
just like any other part of the financial sector, by getting funds from
savers and investing them in financial assets and loans. The rest of the
financial sector is profitable. It seems unrealistic to think that
banks cannot also generate a profit from providing this service. Indeed,
crowd-funding and peer-to-peer lending manage to make profits by extending savings to willing borrowers.
Thus, there is no reason to think that banks in a sovereign money
system wouldn’t be able to make similar profits from providing the exact
same service.
https://www.positivemoney.org/2012/09/lawrence-white-tries-to-argue-for-fractional-reserve-banking/
2. “IT’S UNNECESSARY”
“DEPOSIT INSURANCE MAKES THE BANKING SYSTEM SAFE.”
Governments currently guarantee the liabilities of banks by promising
bank customers that they will be reimbursed, from taxpayer funds, if
the bank fails (i.e. £85,000 per person per bank). By reducing the
incentives for bank customers to ‘run’ on the bank, critics may argue
that Sovereign Money is unnecessary.
However
deposit insurance does not make the system safer, it
actually makes it riskier.
1) It removes the incentives for bank customers to take an interest in the activities of their bank.
2) It leaves banks free to take whatever risks they like without scrutiny from customers.
3) The role of monitoring is therefore left exclusively to the under-resourced regulator.
4) Bank customers, staff and shareholders benefit from the upside of
bank investments, but the taxpayer takes the ultimate losses once the
risk taking leads to a bank failure.
5) Deposit insurance leads to greater risk-taking by the banks (moral hazard), and therefore greater risk of failure.
https://www.positivemoney.org/2011/01/no-solutions-on-bbc2-are-britains-banks-too-big-to-save/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2013/02/detlev-schlichter-on-positive-money-a-response/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2012/11/criticisms-of-positive-money-by-mike-robinson-of-uk-column/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2012/06/regulate-banks-or-go-for-the-two-account-system/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/10/can-remove-state-support-banks/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2013/05/two-main-problems-with-deposit-insurance/
“REMOVE STATE SUPPORT FOR BANKS & LET MARKETS DISCIPLINE THEM”
This argument proposes that banks would not have taken so much risk
without the safety nets provided by governments and central banks.
Without these safety nets, those banks that were mismanaged would
have
been liquidated and would have made way for new market entrants with
better business practices. The argument makes sense, but the policy
prescription of removing deposit insurance and lender of last resort
whilst keeping the current structure of banking is a dead end. If
deposit insurance (the £85k on bank balances) were officially withdrawn,
the first rumour of potential problems at a large bank would be enough
to encourage a run on that bank. In such a situation, the government
would immediately re-instate deposit insurance (in the same way that
deposit insurance caps were raised or removed during the financial
crisis). Likewise, central banks are unlikely to have the nerve to
refuse to lend to a bank in distress, knowing that the failure of one
bank could rapidly cause a breakdown in the payments system.
These problems will remain as long as the payment system consists of
liabilities of commercial banks, because any bank failure threatens the
payment system and therefore the entire real economy.
A sovereign money system
tackles this problem by separating the payments system (made up mainly
of Transaction Accounts) from the risk-taking activities of banks, and
allows taxpayer-funded safety nets to be removed without risking a panic in the process.
https://www.positivemoney.org/2012/06/regulate-banks-or-go-for-the-two-account-system/
“WE JUST NEED BETTER REGULATION”
The better regulation view assumes that regulators actually have
control over what banks do. This is an extremely optimistic view, for a
number of reasons:
1) The banking sector has far more funds and resources at its
disposal than any public body designed to regulate it. Therefore, banks
would be able to mobilise substantially more resources for bypassing
certain policy reforms, under the guise of financial innovation, than
regulators would have in order to prevent them from doing so.
2) If regulatory policies are somewhat successful, as in 1950s and
1960s, their role can be downplayed by lobbyists and eventually removed
on the grounds that such restrictions were never required to begin with.
3) The financial system is presently so complex (compared to the
1950s-1970s) that it is becoming increasingly more difficult to
regulate.
4) Only regulating and not restructuring, will most likely result in a
more convoluted financial system, making it even more difficult
regulate.
5) Small banks cannot cope with huge amounts of regulation, in other
countries this has resulted in small banks being merged with bigger
banks, an unintended consequence.
6) The problems with the current monetary set-up are systemic. What
is needed is systemic change, not a number of new rules that will keep
the current inherently unstable system intact.
As Andy Haldane at the Bank of England has said, what is needed is
greater simplicity: banks that can fail without threatening the payments
system or
calling on taxpayer funds. Our approach ensures that private
risk-taking remains private, and losses cannot be socialised. That
said, any measures to change regulations to direct more credit and
lending to the real economy would be beneficial.
https://www.positivemoney.org/2011/01/independent-commission-on-banking-released-responses/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2011/01/disappointing-half-time-report-from-the-independent-commission-on-banking/.
https://www.positivemoney.org/2011/01/basel-accords-mark-market/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2012/09/vickers-had-no-idea-what-narrow-banking-is/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2012/06/regulate-banks-or-go-for-the-two-account-system/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/11/regulation-banks-solution-ignores-larger-issues-play/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/06/disagree-ann-pettifor/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/05/cant-leave-power-create-money-hands-banks-regulators-open-democracy/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/04/ann-pettifor-there-will-be-no-shortage-of-money/
3. “EVEN IF IT WORKS IT WILL BE DAMAGING”
“IT IS UNREASONABLE TO EXPECT THE PUBLIC TO ASSESS THE RISK OF INVESTMENT ACCOUNTS”
Some scrutiny from bank customers is important. We do not think that
the average Investment Account holder will spend their time poring
through the bank’s financial statements. However, the fact that
Investment Account holders must take some risk does create the
opportunity for banks to differentiate themselves − based on the types
of investment opportunities they offer to the public. This is in
contrast to the current situation, in which all banks offer liabilities
that are underwritten by the government and therefore ‘risk-free’, and
simply compete by offering the highest interest rates.
The idea that bank deposits are somehow special and must be protected
from the risk of loss seems rather myopic, as it overlooks the fact
that the majority of most people’s wealth is invested in financial
assets (or property) that is not protected. If we believe that no bank
deposit should ever lose money, why does the same argument not apply to
those who invest their pensions in the stock market, or in buy-to-let
property? In addition, other forms of finance such as peer-to-peer
lending are showing rapid signs of growth despite not being insured by
the government.
Investment Accounts in a Sovereign Money system would carry varying
degrees of risk, and would not be guaranteed by the government.
Investment Account holders would need to choose their respective desired
level of risk at the point of opening the Investment Account. The terms
of the account would explain how any losses on the underlying
investments are split between the bank and Investment Account holders
collectively. Losses incurred by the bank will eat into its loan loss
provisions and own capital. Losses passed onto Investment Account
holders will reduce the balance of their accounts.
For example, the low-risk low-return accounts may say that the bank
would take the losses up to 7% of the value of their Investment Accounts
(an amount that should be covered by loan loss provisions plus own
capital), whilst the customers would take losses proportionately on any
amount past this point. In contrast, on higher-risk accounts, which may
fund more speculative activities, the terms may be that any losses are
split equally between the bank and the Investment Account holders.
The noteworthy points are: a) Investment Account holders would be
able to choose how much risk they want to take, and that b) in the worst
case scenario, Investment Account holders may end up losing part of
their investment.
“IT WOULD LEAD TO A SHORTAGE OF CREDIT, DEFLATION, AND RECESSION”
The basic premise of this argument is that removing the banking
sector’s ability to create money will reduce its capacity to make loans,
and as a result the economy will suffer. However, this ignores several
crucial issues: 1) The recycling of loan repayments coupled with savings
would be sufficient to fund business and consumer lending as well as a
non-inflationary level of mortgage lending. 2) There is an implicit
assumption that the level of credit provided by the banking sector today
is appropriate for the economy. Banks lend too much in the good times
(particularly for unproductive purposes) and not enough in the aftermath
of a bust. 3) The argument is based on the assumption that bank lending
primarily funds the real economy. However, loans for consumption and to
non-financial businesses account for as little as 16% of total bank
lending. The rest of bank lending does not contribute directly to GDP.
4) Inflows of sovereign money permit the levels of private debt to
shrink without a reduction in the level of money in circulation,
disposable income of households would increase, and with it, spending in
the real economy – boosting revenue for businesses. 5) If there were a
shortage of funds across the entire banking system, particularly for
lending to businesses that contribute to GDP, the central bank always
has the option to create and auction newly created money to the banks,
on the provision that these funds are lent into the real economy (i.e.
to non-financial businesses).
https://www.positivemoney.org/2013/04/the-alleged-deflationary-effect-of-full-reserve-banking/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2012/09/vickers-had-no-idea-what-narrow-banking-is/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2012/09/lawrence-white-tries-to-argue-for-fractional-reserve-banking/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2012/07/george-selgin-favours-fractional-reserve-banking/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2015/01/new-report-stripping-banks-power-create-money-cause-shortage-money-high-unemployment-economic-decline/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/11/sovereign-money-response-andrea-leadsom-economic-secretary-treasury/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/06/disagree-ann-pettifor/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/04/ann-pettifor-there-will-be-no-shortage-of-money/
“IT WOULD BE INFLATIONARY / HYPERINFLATIONARY”
Some argue that a Sovereign Money system would be inflationary or
hyperinflationary. There are a number of reasons why this argument is
wrong: 1) Money creation can only become inflationary if it exceeds the
productive capacity of the economy (or if all the newly created money is
injected into an area of the economy that has no spare capacity). Our
proposals state that the central bank would have a primary mandate to
keep prices stable and inflation low. If money creation feeds through
into inflation, the central bank would need to slow down or cease
creating new money until inflationary pressures fell. 2) Hyperinflation
is typically a symptom of some underlying economic collapse, as happened
in Zimbabwe and Weimar Republic Germany. When the economy collapses,
tax revenues fall and desperate governments may resort to financing
their spending through money creation. The lesson from episodes of
hyperinflation is that strong governance, checks and balances are
vitally important to if any economy is going to function properly..
Hyperinflation is not a consequence of monetary policy; it is a symptom
of a state that has lost control of its tax base. Appendix I of
Modernising Money covers this process in depth, looking at the case of
Zimbabwe.
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/05/hyperinflation-born-extremis/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/04/ignorant-live-fear-hyperinflation/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2013/05/would-positive-money-system-be-inflationary/
“INTEREST RATES WOULD BE TOO HIGH”
There are two assumptions behind this critique: 1) A shortage of
credit would prompt interest rates to rise to harmful levels. 2) As
savings accounts would no longer be guaranteed by the government, savers
would demand much higher interest rates in order to encourage them to
save.
Sections above explains how a sovereign money system will not result
in a shortage of money or credit in the economy, thus there is no reason
for interest rates to start rising rapidly.
The second point is disproven by the existence of peer-to-peer
lenders, which work in a similar way to the lending function of banks in
a sovereign money system. They take funds from savers and lend them to
borrowers, rather than creating money in the process of lending. There
is no government guarantee, meaning that savers must take the loss of
any investments. The peer-to-peer lender provides a facility
to
distribute risk over a number of loans, so that the failure of one
borrower to repay only has a small impact on a larger number of savers.
Despite the fact that the larger banks benefit from a government
guarantee, as of May 2014, the interest rates on a personal loan from
peer-to-peer lender Zopa is currently 5.7% (for £5,000 over 3 years),
beating Nationwide Building Society’s 8.9% and Lloyd’s 12.9%. This shows
that there is no logical reason why interest rates would rise under a
banking system where banks must raise funds from savers before making
loans, without the benefit of a taxpayer-backed guarantee on their
liabilities.
https://www.positivemoney.org/2012/07/eleven-arguments-against-interest-rate-adjustments/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/06/disagree-ann-pettifor/
“IT WOULD HAND OVER THE PRINTING PRESS TO POLITICIANS”
Many critics misunderstand Sovereign Money, and assume that Sovereign
Money would equate to allowing the government to print as much money
into existence as they want. However, it is important to note that
politicians are not directly given control over money creation, because
of the risk that political pressures could lead the government to abuse
this power. Therefore, the decision over how much new money to create
should be taken, as it is now, by the Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) at
the central bank in line with their democratically mandated targets.
Likewise, the process should be designed so that the central bank is not
able to gain influence over government policy.
In practice this means that the MPC and the Bank of England should
not have any say over what the new money should be used for (this is a
decision to be taken solely by the government) whilst the government
should have no say over how much money is created (which is a decision
for the MPC). Decisions on money creation would be taken independently
of government, by a newly formed Money Creation Committee (or by the
existing Monetary Policy Committee). The Committee would be accountable
to the Treasury Select Committee, a cross-party committee of Members of
Parliament who scrutinise the actions of the Bank of England and
Treasury. The Committee would no longer set interest rates, which would
now be set in the market.
With these two factors in mind, the procedure for the central bank
and the government cooperating to increase spending is relatively
simple. First the central bank would take a decision over how much money
to create and grant to the government. Once in possession of the money,
the government could use it to increase spending, or lower taxes.
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/05/neither-profit-seeking-bankers-vote-seeking-politicians-can-trusted-power-create-money/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2013/04/dirk-bezemer-on-positive-money-a-response/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2013/02/detlev-schlichter-on-positive-money-a-response/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2012/11/criticisms-of-positive-money-by-mike-robinson-of-uk-column/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2012/07/eleven-arguments-against-interest-rate-adjustments/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/11/sovereign-money-response-andrea-leadsom-economic-secretary-treasury/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/06/disagree-ann-pettifor/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2013/05/would-positive-money-system-be-inflationary/
“IT WOULD BE DIFFICULT TO PREVENT PARTISAN BEHAVIOUR BY THE CENTRAL BANK”
If the central bank decided the economy was faltering due to a
shortage of money, and decided to create additional money to be
allocated to government, it would be for government to decide how that
money was to be spent. If instead, the central bank decided that the
extra money should be lent to the banking sector, then it would be the
banking sector that decided which projects to finance. Since the
monetary committee does not have any decision making power to
influencehow the newly money is spent, it is difficult for it to behave
in a partisan manner.
When the central bank creates new money and transfers it to the
government’s account, it would be for the government to decide how that
money was to be spent. If the central bank feels that there is a
shortage of credit in the real economy, and decides to creates money to
lend to banks (in order to finance their lending to non-financial
businesses) then it is the banks that decide which firms and projects to
finance. Since the Monetary Committee does not have any decision making
power to influence how the newly money is spent, it is difficult for it
to behave in a partisan manner.
Despite this, the monetary committee should implement the safeguards
that are typically used to protect against partisan behavior by any
committee or body, such as having staggered terms and submitting any
appointments to possible veto by a cross-party group such as the
Treasury Select Committee.
https://www.positivemoney.org/2013/02/detlev-schlichter-on-positive-money-a-response/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2012/11/criticisms-of-positive-money-by-mike-robinson-of-uk-column/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/11/sovereign-money-response-andrea-leadsom-economic-secretary-treasury/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/06/disagree-ann-pettifor/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/05/power-create-money-safer-state-banks/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/05/neither-profit-seeking-bankers-vote-seeking-politicians-can-trusted-power-create-money/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2013/05/would-positive-money-system-be-inflationary/
“IT IS OVER RELIANT ON CENTRAL PLANNING”
This critique argues that placing the power to create money in the
hands of a body at the central bank is overly centralized, amounts to
central planning or relies on rule by technocrats.
Firstly, does the proposal amount to ‘central planning’? The Money
Creation Committee would be responsible for just two things: a)
identifying the increase in the money stock needed to promote
non-inflationary growth, and b) monitoring any possibility of a shortage
of credit to the real economy. They are not responsible for deciding
how to spend newly created money, as this decision is given to the
elected government (just as with the decision on how to spend all tax
revenue). Neither are they responsible for deciding which businesses get
loans or investment, as this decision remains with banks (and the
savers who provide them with funds).
Secondly, is this process of money creation over-centralised? We
would argue that the decision over how much money to create necessarily
has to be centralised for a nation. However, the decision over how the
money is spent can be as decentralised as one would wish. The most
decentralised method of distribution would be to divide the newly
created money equally between all citizens and allow them to spend it as
they see fit. But decentralisation of the decision of how much money to
create is unworkable. If the decision is decentralised by giving a
range of banks (whether private or publicly owned) the power to create
money, every individual bank has the incentive to create more money to
maximise loan revenues. The overall result will be excessive levels of
money creation. If each bank is to be given a quota for how much money
to create, then this necessitates a central decision maker again. If the
decision were decentralised to say, local authority governments, who
were permitted to create money up until the point that it started to
fuel inflation, then every local authority would have the incentive to
create as much money as quickly as possible, in order to create and
spend the maximum amount in advance of other local authority governments
and before the combined effect led to inflation.
https://www.positivemoney.org/2013/04/dirk-bezemer-on-positive-money-a-response/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2013/02/detlev-schlichter-on-positive-money-a-response/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2012/10/full-reserve-banking-does-not-mean-a-bank-bailout/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2012/07/eleven-arguments-against-interest-rate-adjustments/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2012/03/myths-money-banking/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2015/01/new-report-stripping-banks-power-create-money-cause-shortage-money-high-unemployment-economic-decline/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/11/sovereign-money-response-andrea-leadsom-economic-secretary-treasury/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/06/disagree-ann-pettifor/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/05/power-create-money-safer-state-banks/
“IT REQUIRES CONTROL BY TECHNOCRATS.”
This is very similar to the argument above: A centralised committee
can’t possibly make a decision as complex as how much money is needed in
the economy as a whole.
Currently, the MPC make decisions on interest rates that have huge
influence over the returns that savers make on their pensions, on how
much householders pay on their mortgages, and how much businesses must
pay in interest to banks. This is a blunt tool with far-reaching
consequences. Indeed, the Bank of England suggests that it can take up
to three years for it to start taking an effect.
On the other hand, conventional Quantitative Easing is an extremely
complex technocratic process. Not only is the majority of society
confused by its mechanics and how it works, but there is still a large
debate as to whether it actually works.
In contrast, the creation of new money in the controlled and measured
manner proposed in Sovereign Money has a much more precise and
concentrated impact, and does not have the same level of ‘collateral
damage’ upon the wider economy.
https://www.positivemoney.org/2012/07/eleven-arguments-against-interest-rate-adjustments/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/11/sovereign-money-response-andrea-leadsom-economic-secretary-treasury/
“THE SHADOW BANKING SECTOR WOULD SIMPLY CREATE
SUBSTITUTES FOR MONEY. NEAR-MONIES WOULD EMERGE AND THE CENTRAL BANK
WOULD LOSE CONTROL OF MONEY CREATION.”
The concern here is that restricting the ability of banks to create
money will lead to the shadow- banking sector creating close substitutes
for sovereign money, thus circumventing the intention of these reforms.
However, there is minimal risk of this happening, for a couple of
reasons:
1) Unless there is a shortage of money, there will be no demand for
money substitutes. So this argument only applies if there is a genuine
shortage of money in the economy. We’ve addressed the reasons why this
is unlikely above.
2) Even in a recent case of shortage of money in the economy (i.e.
the years following the financial crisis) there is little evidence of
‘near monies’ rising up and taking the place of bank deposits on any
economically significant scale. Any money substitutes created by the
shadow banking system would be risk bearing, whereas money in
Transaction Accounts would be entirely risk-free. The company or shadow
bank attempting to issue near-monies would have to offer significant
advantages over a standard Transaction Account in order to compensate
for this risk.
However, the emergence of near-monies is actually extremely easy to
prevent. For any shadow bank’s liabilities to function as near-monies,
they would have to be as easy to make payments with as normal sovereign
money in a Transaction Account. This would mean that it must be possible
to make payments with them using the same payment networks as the banks
do: BACS, CHAPS, Faster Payments and so on in the UK. Therefore any
shadow bank that wishes to connect to these payment systems must be
required to operate as a Transaction Account provider, and would
therefore have no ability to create money. Any shadow bank that was not
willing to work in this way would find the payment services it offered
would be less widely accepted and therefore less useful, and not an
effective substitute for sovereign money.
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/12/possible-stop-banks-creating-money-shadow-banks-just-take/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/11/sovereign-money-response-andrea-leadsom-economic-secretary-treasury/
“THIS IS A MONETARIST POLICY.”
Currently, the Monetary Policy Committee attempts to control bank
lending – and therefore the quantity of broad money in the economy – by
influencing the interest rate at which banks lend to each other on the
interbank market. After the reform, the MCC would have direct control
over the money stock and so there would be no need for the MCC to use
interest rates to affect it. This has only a superficial resemblance to
the monetarist policies of the 1980s. It is important to note that one
reason monetarism was disastrous, was because central banks were
attempting to control the growth in bank deposits (mainly through bank
lending) through restricting the monetary base.
The theory was that the quantity of money on deposit at the central
bank (reserves) could be used to restrict the quantity of deposits at
private banks (broad money). This policy was in part based on a money
multiplier view of bank lending – that banks required deposits (or
central bank reserves) before they could make loans. However, the money
multiplier model is incorrect – loans in fact create deposits and
reserves are required by banks only to settle payments between
themselves. In short, base money is endogenous to the creation of bank
deposits and is supplied by the central bank on demand. Central Banks
were unable to credibly restrict the supply of reserves to any private
bank once it had made loans, as to do so could have led to the bank in
question being unable to make payments to other banks. This could have
led to a bank run and as such would have contravened the central bank’s
remit to maintain financial stability.
In addition, monetarists were mainly concerned with inflation, and
saw all money creation
as inflationary. In contrast, a sovereign money
system recognizes that there are situations in which money creation
actually raises demand and output rather than simply causing inflation.
Monetarists also saw inflation as the main threat to the economy, and
were willing to let unemployment rise in order to keep inflation under
control (although this did not work). In contrast, proposals for a
sovereign money system have a strong focus on how money creation can be
used responsibly to boost employment and output.
https://www.positivemoney.org/2012/10/does-full-reserve-banking-equal-monetarism/
https://www.positivemoney.org/2014/08/sovereign-money-system-monetarism/